Michigan Journal of International Law Michigan Journal of International Law
Volume 43 Issue 3
2022
Tax Harmony: The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax Harmony: The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum
Tax Tax
Reuven Avi-Yonah
University of Michigan Law School
Young Ran (Christine) Kim
Cardozo School of Law
Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mjil
Part of the International Law Commons, International Trade Law Commons, Taxation-Transnational
Commons, and the Tax Law Commons
Recommended Citation Recommended Citation
Reuven Avi-Yonah & Young R. Kim,
Tax Harmony: The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax
, 43
MICH. J. INT'L L. 505 (2022).
Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mjil/vol43/iss3/2
https://doi.org/10.36642/mjil.43.3.tax
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Michigan Journal of International Law at University of
Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Michigan Journal of
International Law by an authorized editor of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more
information, please contact mlaw[email protected].
505
TAX HARMONY:
THE PROMISE AND PITFALLS OF THE
GLOBAL MINIMUM TAX
Reuven Avi-Yonah
*
and Young Ran (Christine) Kim
A
BSTRACT
The rise of globalization has become a double-edged sword for
countries seeking to implement a beneficial tax policy. On one hand,
there are increased opportunities for attracting foreign capital and
the benefits that increased jobs and tax revenue brings to a society.
However, there is also much more tax competition among countries
to attract foreign capital and investment. As tax competition has
grown, effective corporate tax rates have continued to be cut,
creating a “race-to-the-bottom” issue.
In 2021, 137 countries forming the OECD/G20 Inclusive Frame-
work on BEPS passed a major milestone in reforming international
tax by successfully introducing the framework of a global minimum
corporate tax, known as Pillar Two. It aims to set a floor for
corporate tax rates with various corrective measures so that
multinational enterprises’ income will be taxed once in either
source country or residence country at a substantive tax rate.
Hence, Pillar Two is the first implementation of the “single tax
principle” at the global level. Because Pillar Two requires an
unprecedented amount of coordination among countries, it is im-
portant to understand Pillar Two thoroughly so that countries can
maneuver the challenges of implementation, while still enjoying the
ultimate benefit that would come from this global tax harmony.
This Article analyzes the issues of tax competition and why most
countries in the world have come to the conclusion that a global
minimum tax is needed. This Article explains the single tax principle
as the theoretical underpinning of Pillar Two, breaks down the
principles and policies that comprise Pillar Two, and anticipates
* Irwin I. Cohn Professor of Law, University of Michigan Law School.
Professor of Law, Cardozo School of Law. We are grateful to participants of the
Boston College Law School Tax Colloquium, National Tax Association Annual Conference,
and Rocky Mountain for Junior Scholars Workshop for helpful comments. Special thanks to
the University of Utah’s Albert and Elaine Borchard Fund for Faculty Excellence. Ryan An-
derson, Benton Eskelsen, and Darian Hackney provided excellent research assistance.
506 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
what promise and pitfalls passage of the global minimum tax will
bring. Because the basis of Pillar Two is a direct extension of the
Global Intangible Low Tax Income (GILTI) and Base Erosion and
Anti-Abuse Tax (BEAT) provisions of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, it
is reasonable to anticipate that the global minimum tax will be
considered a success if it is implemented by all the G20 countries.
INTRODUCTION
On October 8, 2021, 136 countries signed the Organisation for Econom-
ic Co-operation and Development (“OECD”) Base Erosion and Profit Shift-
ing (“BEPS”) statement (“the Statement”), which embodies the farthest-
reaching revolution in international taxation since the 1920s.
1
The State-
ment marks the beginning of a new international tax regime for the twenty-
first century. Fit for a modern, digital, globalized world, the Statement em-
braces the ideal of corporate tax harmonization to combat the race to the
bottom that has dominated international taxation since the advent of globali-
zation in the 1980s.
2
This article will discuss the promises and pitfalls of the new interna-
tional tax regime, as embodied in Pillar Two of the Statement. The State-
ment envisages this regime as built on two pillars.
3
Pillar One is focused on
expanding source country taxing rights on the income of large multinational
enterprises. In particular, it targets digital companies such as Facebook or
Google that are able to extract profits from a source jurisdiction without a
physical presence.
4
We address Pillar One in a companion article, thus we
will not engage with it here.
5
1. Statement on a Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising from the
Digitalisation of the Economy, O
RG. FOR ECON. COOP. & DEV. [“OECD”] (Oct. 8, 2021),
http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/statement-on-a-two-pillar-solution-to-address-the-tax-challenges-
arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-the-economy-october-2021.pdf [hereinafter, Statement]. At
first, 136 jurisdictions out of the 140 members of the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on
BEPS joined the deal, the G20 finance ministers approved the agreement on October 13,
2021, and the G20 leaders approved on October 31, 2021. G20 Leaders Confirm Commitment
to Global Tax Changes Under BEPS 2.0, EY
TAX NEWS UPDATE (Nov. 2, 2021),
http://taxnews.ey.com/news/2021-1991-g20-leaders-confirm-commitment-to-global-tax-
changes-under-beps-20. As of November 4, 2021, 137 countries and jurisdictions joined a
new two-pillar plan.
OECD: BEPS, Inclusive Framework on Base Erosion and Profit Sharing,
OECD, http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/ (last visited Mar. 11, 2021).
2. The race to the bottom is a term to describe tax competition. This Article uses the
two terms interchangeably depending on the context.
3. Statement, supra note 1.
4. See Reuven Avi-Yonah, Young Ran (Christine) Kim & Karen Sam, A New Frame-
work for Digital Taxation, 63 H
ARV. INTL L.J. (forthcoming 2022).
5. See id.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 507
This article will discuss the circumstances that led to more than 130 ju-
risdictions around the world agreeing to implement the global minimum tax
and the single tax principle of Pillar Two. The double-edged sword of glob-
alization and tax competition created difficulties for many countries, as they
were being increasingly squeezed by multinational enterprises to provide
lower corporate tax rates and tax holidays as conditions for receiving for-
eign investment. While increased foreign direct investment (“FDI”) can cre-
ate higher-paying job opportunities, economic growth, and the societal ben-
efits of an increased tax base, these benefits are greatly diminished when the
country needs to offer exceedingly low tax rates or tax holiday enticements
to secure the FDI.
6
As tax competition has grown, global effective corporate
tax rates have continued to be cut, creating a “race-to-the-bottom” where the
tax rate needed to attract foreign investment is so low that there is almost no
net benefit to the society securing the foreign capital.
Countries can address this problem by closing off their trade borders or
by making cutbacks to their social safety net.
7
However, the better solution
is to limit tax competition.
8
Pillar Two aims to address the issue of “race-to-
the-bottom” tax competition and achieve tax harmonization through the
adoption of a global minimum tax. Multinational enterprises that meet the
€750 million Euro revenue threshold—regardless of which jurisdiction they
are headquartered in or operate from—will be subject to a global minimum
tax.
9
But the way this new regime works is quite complex, because multina-
tional enterprises’ income involves at least two countries—the source coun-
try where income is generated, and the residence country where investors
are located.
As an example, consider that Orange, a hypothetical U.S. multinational
enterprise, has a subsidiary corporation in Ireland.
10
The Irish subsidiary’s
income from its trade or business is considered active income, and Ireland
(the source country) has primary jurisdiction to tax that income under the
benefits principle.
11
Ideally, Ireland will tax the income at a substantive tax
6. OPTIONS FOR LOW INCOME COUNTRIES’EFFECTIVE AND EFFICIENT USE OF TAX
INCENTIVES FOR INVESTMENT,INTL MONETARY FUND [“IMF”] (2015), http://www.imf.org
/external/np/g20/pdf/101515.pdf.
7. See infra Part I.
8. See id.
9.Statement, supra note 1, at 4. Such a revenue threshold will be determined under
Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (“BEPS”) Action 13 (country by country reporting), and a
tax base will be determined by reference to financial accounting income.
10. This hypothetical example is similar to Apple Inc.’s structure, which has been criti-
cized for avoiding taxes through its Irish subsidiaries. See, e.g., Simon Bowers, Apple’s Cash
Mountain, How It Avoids Tax, and the Irish Link,T
HE IRISH TIMES (Nov. 6, 2017),
http://www.irishtimes.com/business/apple-s-cash-mountain-how-it-avoids-tax-and-the-irish-link-
1.3281734.
11. Under the benefits principle, active income from trade or business is primarily as-
signed to the source country’s tax jurisdiction (and the residence country has secondary juris-
diction), while passive income, such as dividends, interest, and royalty, is primarily assigned
508 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
rate. However, with the large negotiating power of massive multinational
enterprises, source countries do not always tax them at substantive rates.
Under Pillar Two’s global minimum tax, if the Irish subsidiary’s income is
taxed below the agreed minimum tax rate of fifteen percent in Ireland (the
source country), then the parent entity in the United States (the residence
country) is required to include such under-taxed income in its U.S. tax base
and pay the difference in additional taxes to the United States. If the United
States (the residence country) has not enacted Pillar Two’s income inclusion
rule as a corrective measure, then the Irish subsidiary’s tax deduction in Ire-
land (the source country) would be denied. Alternatively, an equivalent ad-
justment would be made to the extent that the low-tax income of the Irish
subsidiary is not subject to minimum tax under an income inclusion rule.
As illustrated in the example, the mechanics of Pillar Two can be quite
complicated. However, the objective of Pillar Two is clear: to implement
the goal of the single tax principle (that is, “full taxation”) in international
tax, thereby solving the problems created by the tax competition prevalent
in the twentieth century.
12
The single tax principle requires multinational
enterprises’ income to be subject to taxation once. By doing so, it prevents
both double taxation and double non-taxation. However, there are nuances
to the single tax principle. First, the country (residence or source country)
that can exercise primary tax jurisdiction is determined based on whether
income is active or passive according to the benefits principle.
13
With active
income, the source country has primary tax jurisdiction, and the residence
country has secondary jurisdiction. If taxation by the source country is sub-
stantial, the residence country will yield its secondary taxing right by allow-
ing a foreign tax credit to prevent double taxation.
14
On the other hand, if
the first taxation is nominal (below the minimum rate), it is not considered
to have satisfied the imposition of a “single tax,” and thus corrective rules
by the secondary tax jurisdiction should apply to prevent double non-
taxation. Thus, the single tax principle suggests that all income of multina-
the residence country’s tax jurisdiction (and the source country has secondary jurisdiction).
This principle is a product of the compromise among nations in 1923, driven by four econo-
mists in the League of Nations. See infra Part II.A; Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, The Structure of
International Taxation: A Proposal for Simplification, 74 T
EX.L.REV. 1301, 1305 (1996).
12. The single tax principle provides that corporate profits should be subject to a mini-
mum tax and that if the country with the primary right to tax such income (source or resi-
dence) does not impose tax at the minimum level, the other country involved should tax it. For
a discussion of the single tax principle, see e.g., infra Part II.A.; Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Who
Invented the Single Tax Principle? An Essay on the History of US Treaty Policy, 59 N.Y.L.
S
CH.L.REV. 305 (2015) [hereinafter, Single Tax Principle]. For full taxation, see Ruth Ma-
son, The Transformation of International Tax, 114 A
M.J.INTL L. 353 (2020) [hereinafter,
Transformation].
13. For a discussion of the benefits principle, see supra note 11.
14. See, e.g., I.R.C. § 901 (upholding a residence country’s obligation to prevent dou-
ble taxation by unilaterally granting foreign tax credits).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 509
tionals must be taxed once at a substantive tax rate. Hence, Ruth Mason re-
fers to this principle as “full taxation.
15
The single tax principle was first conceived of in the early twentieth
century as the basis for the foreign tax credit.
16
The United States and other
countries began to practically implement the principle in the 1960s and
1970s.
17
However, until recently, it had not been fully integrated into inter-
national tax because of fierce tax competition and many unilateral tax poli-
cies that are inconsistent with the single tax principle.
18
Many scholars did
not believe that reasonable tax harmony could be achieved through the sin-
gle tax principle, and thus, it had been somewhat controversial.
19
Nonethe-
less, the OECD BEPS 1.0 Project in the 2010s aspired to achieve the single
tax principle through global tax harmonization.
20
Perhaps because of linger-
ing doubts about its feasibility, the project achieved limited success.
21
The passage of the U.S. Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (“TCJA”) of 2017
played a crucial role in establishing the feasibility of the single tax principle.
The TCJA adopted two new innovative breakthrough tax mechanisms: the
Global Intangible Low Tax Income (“GILTI”) rule for residence taxation
and the Base Erosion Anti-Abuse Tax (“BEAT”) rule for source taxation.
22
These two rules showed how the single tax principle can be achieved unilat-
erally to combat base erosion and profit shifting by U.S. multinational en-
terprises. The success of the TCJA also demonstrated conceptually that
there are ways to stop tax competition if the Group of Twenty (“G20”)
countries implement the single tax principle fully with proper corrective
measures.
23
Building upon those previous efforts, Pillar Two implements the single
tax principle globally for the first time by introducing a global minimum tax
rate of fifteen percent, and various corrective measures, such as the Income
Inclusion Rule (“IIR”) for residence taxation, and the Undertaxed Payment
Rule (“UTPR”) (denial of deduction) and Subject To Tax Rule (“STTR”)
15.Transformation, supra note 12, at 22, 25.
16. See infra Part II.A.1.
17. See id.
18. See id.
19. See infra Part II.A.2.
20. See infra Part II.B.
21. See, e.g., Mindy Herzfeld, The Case Against BEPS: Lessons for Tax Coordination,
21 F
L.TAX REV. 1 (2017).
22. The Global Intangible Low Tax Income (“GILTI”) rule imposed the U.S. tax as
residence taxation on certain foreign subsidiaries’ income from intangible assets, and Base
Erosion Anti-Abuse Tax (“BEAT”) denies deductions in the U.S. as source taxation if the de-
ductible payments are unlikely to be subject to residence-based taxation. I.R.C. §§ 951A, 59A.
See infra Part II.C.
23.SeeLilian V. Faulhaber, Taxing Tech: The Future of Digital Taxation, 39 V
A.TAX
REV. 145, 175 (2019) [hereinafter, Taxing Tech].
510 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
for source taxation.
24
Unlike Pillar One, which requires changing more than
3,000 tax treaties with the participation of over 130 source jurisdictions, Pil-
lar Two can generally be implemented unilaterally through domestic legisla-
tion with no changes to existing tax treaties.
25
More importantly, Pillar Two
only requires cooperation by the G20, which are home to over ninety per-
cent of the world’s largest multinational enterprises (“MNEs”), because it
offers strong corrective measures exercised by residence countries. Pillar
Two is therefore more likely to be implemented than Pillar One. Also, the
two pillars deal with different problems—Pillar One with physical presence
and source taxation and Pillar Two with a global minimum tax and resi-
dence taxation—and can conceptually be separated from each other.
The benefits that Pillar Two is expected to bring to the world are signif-
icant. At a global minimum tax rate of fifteen percent, approximately $150
billion U.S. dollars in additional global tax revenues will be generated each
year.
26
The various corrective measures imposed on both source and resi-
dence countries would reduce MNEs’ motivation to engage in base erosion
and profit shifting, because they would be paying a substantial “single tax
no matter where they are located, or where their profits are attributed.
27
Despite its promise, there are still some concerns about Pillar Two. The
fifteen percent global minimum tax rate is relatively low compared to the
average G20 corporate tax rate of about twenty-seven percent.
28
The sub-
stance carve-outs in the Statement also raise concerns that Pillar Two may
still allow a certain level of tax competition.
29
Also, there are concerns that,
because Pillar Two gives the priority to residence taxation (via the IIR) over
source taxation (via the UTPR/STTR), it is skewed toward the interests of
the G20 countries over those of developing countries.
30
Although there is
some truth to this critique, its significance depends on another question: are
tax holidays for FDI the result of a careful cost/benefit analysis by source
countries, or are tax holidays the result of pressure exerted by the MNEs and
the availability of other potential jurisdictions for investment? If the answer
is the latter, the critique is less convincing because the tax competition prob-
lem can be solved by the IIR and residence taxation, which neutralize the
multinationals’ incentive to shop around the source countries for lower tax
rates.
24. See infra Part III.A.
25. See infra Part IV.B.3.
26. See infra Part IV.A.1.
27. See infra Part IV.A.2.
28. BEPS Monitoring Group Comments on the Model Rules for a Global Anti-Base-
Erosion Minimum Corporate Tax, 105 T
AX NOTES INTL 1421 (Mar. 21, 2022); Elke Asen,
Corporate Tax Rates Around the World, 2020,T
AX FOUND. (Dec. 9, 2020),
http://taxfoundation.org/publications/corporate-tax-rates-around-the-world/. The average cor-
porate tax rate, as of 2020, for the G20 is 26.96 percent.
29. See infra Part IV.B.2.
30. See infra Part IV.B.1.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 511
This article is one of the first wave of comprehensive scholarly papers
to describe Pillar Two of the new international tax regime and to analyze its
theoretic underpinnings.
31
Part I defines the tax competition problem Pillar
Two was designed to address. Part II presents the existing efforts to resolve
tax competition. It discusses the historical origins and development of the
single tax principle and explains the TCJA’s crucial role in leading to the
fruition of Pillar Two. Part III analyzes Pillar Two as a new solution to tax
competition. It highlights three rules in the Statement (the IIR, UTPR, and
STTR) and introduces the implementation plans by the OECD/G20 and the
United States in the Build Back Better (“BBB”) Act. Part IV addresses the
contribution, benefits, and potential challenges of Pillar Two. It concludes
by reflecting on how, in retrospect, Pillar Two fits in with the two principles
underlying the century-old regime, namely the benefits principle and the
single tax principle.
I. HE PROBLEM OF TAX COMPETITION
The current age of globalization has made countries face the trilemma
of balancing (1) FDI-driven job creation and economic growth, (2) econom-
ic openness and competition from peers, and (3) securing a social safety
net.
32
First, globalization has allowed many countries to utilize FDI to cre-
ate more and better-paying jobs for their citizens,
33
to generate investment
in their economic infrastructure, and to introduce technologies that allow for
modernization.
34
The economic growth of Asian countries, such as Singa-
pore, Hong Kong, South Korea, and Taiwan, is believed to have been pri-
marily initiated by the influx of FDI in the 1950s.
35
These countries’ econ-
31. See e.g., Jinyan Li, The Pillar 2 Undertaxed Payments Rule Departs from Interna-
tional Consensus and Tax Treaties, 105 T
AX NOTES INTL 1401 (Mar. 21, 2022); Chris Wil-
liam Sanchirico, A Game-Theoretic Analysis of Global Minimum Tax Design (U of Penn, Inst
for Law & Econ Research Paper No. 22-19, 2022); Wei Cui, New Puzzles in International Tax
Agreements,T
AX L. REV. (forthcoming).
32. On the importance of curbing tax competition to maintain democracy and the social
safety net under globalization, see Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Globalization, Tax Competition,
and the Fiscal Crisis of the Welfare State, 113 H
ARV.L.REV. 1573 (2000) [hereinafter, Tax
Competition]; Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Globalization, Tax Competition and the Fiscal Crisis of
the Welfare State: A Twentieth Anniversary Retrospective, in T
HINKER,TEACHER,TRAVELER:
R
EIMAGINING INTERNATIONAL TAX,ESSAYS IN HONOR OF H. DAVID ROSENBLOOM 39
(Georg Kofler, Ruth Mason & Alexander Rust eds., 2021).
33. Foreign Direct Investment “is a category of cross-border investment made by a res-
ident in one economy (the direct investor) with the objective of establishing a lasting interest
in an enterprise (the direct investment enterprise) that is resident in an economy other than
that of the direct investor.” OECD,
OECD B
ENCHMARK DEFINITION OF FOREIGN DIRECT
INVESTMENT 17 (4th ed. 2008), http://www.oecd.org/daf/inv/investment-policy/2090148.pdf.
34.SeeYoram Y. Margalioth, Tax Competition, Foreign Direct Investments and
Growth: Using the Tax System to Promote Developing Countries, 23 V
A.TAX REV. 161
(2003).
35. See id. at 163.
512 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
omies have since grown and flourished while the economies of other nations
who were similarly developing in the 1950s have stalled. Many would at-
tribute such contrast to these Asian countries’ ability and success in attract-
ing FDI.
36
Second, a country that opens up its economy to FDI faces the risks that
come with a dependency on foreign capital that may be diverted elsewhere.
These risks come from competition from peer countries vying to attract for-
eign capital to their economy. The epitome of such rivalry is “tax competi-
tion,” which has been prevalent since the twentieth century.
37
Many devel-
oping countries who want to invite FDI to their soil offer a low tax rate to
foreign investors, such as overall low corporate tax rates, or tax holidays
where foreign investors are exempt from taxation for a predetermined peri-
od of time.
38
Such tax competition is harmful to developing countries,
which depend on corporate taxes to a much greater extent than developed
countries.
39
On average, corporate tax accounts for approximately twenty-
four percent of a developing country’s tax revenue, and only around eight
percent of a developed country’s tax revenue.
40
This problem has worsened
as developed countries like Ireland have also begun engaging in tax compe-
tition, putting even more downward pressure on corporate tax rates. Ire-
land’s current corporate tax rate of 12.5 percent is much lower than the
OECD’s average corporate tax rate of 23.51 percent.
41
To compete, devel-
oping countries may have to drop their rates even lower. Tax competition
creates an incentive to continue to lower tax rates or offer other tax incen-
tives to attract more FDI, potentially running these tax rates down to the
point where jurisdictions may receive little to no net revenue benefit from
the FDI. This “race-to-the-bottom” issue may not be apparent if one only
compares statutory tax rates by looking at countries’ published tax rate(s)
for corporate income, but if one looks at the rate foreign corporations are
36.Id. For different uses of tax incentives for FDI across countries, see IMF, supra
note 6.
37. See, e.g., David Elkins, The Merits of Tax Competition in a Globalized Economy,
91 I
ND. L.J. 3 (2016).
38. Tax holiday refers to a government incentive program that offers a tax reduction or
elimination to businesses. See id.
39.SeeIvan O. Ozai, Tax Competition and the Ethics of Burden Sharing, 42 F
ORDHAM
INTL L. J. 61, 68 (2018).
40. Developed countries also have the benefit of their tax revenue from personal in-
come tax typically being three to four times more than their corporate tax revenues. See Avi
Nov, The “Bidding War” to Attract Foreign Direct Investment: The Need for a Global Solu-
tion, 25 V
A.TAX REV. 835 (2006); Richard Bird, The Personal Income Tax,PREMNOTES:
T
AX POLICY NO. 137, June 2001 at 1; Revenue Statistics 2021: Initial Impact of COVID-19
on OECD Tax Revenues, OECD (2021), http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/sites/6e87f932-en
/index.html?itemId=/content/publication/6e87f932-en.
41. Asen, supra note 28. Developed countries’ engagement in tax competition is espe-
cially problematic because they are better able to absorb the negative aspects of creating tax
incentives while still gaining all the same benefits.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 513
actually paying—the effective tax rates—it is evident that poorer countries’
effective tax rates were basically cut in half from 1996 to 2007.
42
Third, a country also needs to maintain an adequate social safety net
and various welfare programs to protect its low-income population from
poverty and hardship. In the United States, the earned income tax credit,
child tax credits, and a cash transfer program called Temporary Assistance
for Needy Families (“TANF”) are examples of this safety net.
43
In Europe,
these safety nets can encompass all health care costs, education, and hous-
ing. Such large safety nets require significant tax revenue, but countries re-
ducing their corporate tax rates or offering tax holidays in order to retain
foreign investors will find maintaining a robust social safety net much more
difficult with a revenue stream that is vulnerable to such downward fluctua-
tions.
44
Therefore, only two sides of the trilemma can be addressed simultane-
ously. If a country is economically open, it must choose between (1) attract-
ing FDI, which requires tax competition and cuts to the social safety net,
and (2) losing FDI by foregoing tax competition and maintaining the social
safety net. If tax competition is inevitable in a globalized economy, a coun-
try may then either (1) close up its economy, preserve its tax revenue, and
forego the benefits of globalization, or (2) open its economy, endure tax
competition, and subject the social safety net to potential volatility and cuts
even though it serves as a crucial buffer against the downsides of globaliza-
tion.
In fact, many European countries have reduced social safety net pro-
grams following the financial crisis in 2008.
45
The United States retreated
from economic openness during the Trump administration.
46
However, nei-
ther approach has been praised as a reasonable solution to the trilemma be-
cause they are each destructive, requiring some fraction of the economy to
sacrifice or be worse off.
47
Hence, the best solution to this trilemma is finding a way to productive-
ly limit tax competition. Stopping destructive tax competition that races to
the bottom is a constructive way to solve the trilemma, and every country
42.SeeLaura Abramovsky, Alexander Klem & David Phillips, Corporate Tax in De-
veloping Countries: Current Trends and Design Issues, 35 F
ISCAL STUD. 4 (2014) (providing
figure 1 at page 569 outlining trends in corporate income taxes in advanced and developing
economies and figure 2 at 570 tracking effective tax rates at different rates of profitability).
43.SeeEarned I.R.C. § 32(a) (Earned Income Tax Credit); I.R.C. § 24(a) (Child Tax
Credits); 42 U.S.C. §§601–19 (Temporary Assistance for Needy Families).
44. See, e.g.,IMF, supra note 6, at 3.
45.SeeMarianne Bitler & Hilary Hoynes, The More Things Change, the More They
Stay the Same? The Safety New and Poverty in the Great Recession. 34 J.
L
AB.ECON. S403
(2016).
46.SeeAdam Posen, The Price of Nostalgia; America’s Self-Defeating Economic Re-
treat,F
OREIGN AFFS. (May 2021), http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2021-
04-20/america-price-nostalgia.
47. See id.
514 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
involved would benefit. The problem, however, is that source countries
hosting FDI cannot curb tax competition unilaterally. If a country declares
that it will not engage in tax competition by offering tax incentives, such as
tax holidays, to MNEs, then these enterprises will invest elsewhere. For ex-
ample, when the Philippines declined to give a tax exemption and $15 mil-
lion USD in tax incentives to General Motors, the FDI was diverted to Thai-
land.
48
The fundamental problem is that modern MNEs are exceedingly
mobile. They can be located in any country with adequate infrastructure and
an educated workforce. The geographic location of the investment does not
matter since intellectual property can be moved at no cost from one location
to another. The need of manufacturing facilities to be regularly updated or
retrofitted for new processes or innovations also serves to make moving to
new locations less cumbersome.
A common practice of MNEs is to assemble a list of countries that are
acceptable in terms of infrastructure and an educated workforce. The MNE
then approaches the government of each country and asks what it would re-
ceive by way of tax breaks if it invested in the country. If confronted by a
refusal to compromise on taxes, the MNE threatens to go elsewhere, and
few politicians can resist the pressure of losing the favorable headlines that
accompany job creation by a major MNE.
49
For example, Intel in the 1990s conducted an auction for its new source
country, pitting Ireland against Israel, and was able to obtain over $1 billion
USD in tax concessions from both countries.
50
More recently, Amazon con-
ducted an auction among U.S. localities to bid to become the locations of its
second headquarters, which ended up in the vicinity of Washington D.C., an
area not lacking in development.
51
The problem of tax competition is most acute in developing countries
because they depend more on corporate tax revenues than richer countries.
The percentage of total revenues from corporate tax in the OECD member
states is around seven to eight percent, but in developing countries it is clos-
er to twenty-four percent.
52
Recognizing the negative impact of tax compe-
tition on the global economy, the OECD issued the Harmful Tax Competi-
tion Report in 1998 to address the problem.
53
However, the problem
48. Gabriella Stern & Rebecca Blumenstein, GM May Locate Major Plant in
Thailand, Not Philippines,W
ALL ST. J. (May 16, 1996), http://www.wsj.com/articles
/SB832194544528469500.
49.SeeAvi-Yonah, Tax Competition, supra note 32, at 1645–46.
50.Id.
51.SeeReuven Avi-Yonah, Orli Avi-Yonah, Nir Fishbien & Hayian Xu, Federalizing
Tax Justice, 53 I
ND.L.REV. 479 (2020).
52. R
EVENUE STATISTICS BROCHURE INITIAL IMPACT OF COVID-19 ON OECD TAX
REVENUES, OECD (2021), http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/revenue-statistics-highlights-
brochure.pdf.
53. H
ARMFUL TAX COMPETITION:AN EMERGING ISSUE, OECD, (1998), http://
www.oecd.org/ctp/harmful/1904176.pdf.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 515
remained unaddressed, perhaps because it was unrealistic to expect that de-
veloped countries would craft a solution to a problem that more seriously
affects developing countries.
Nevertheless, the harm from tax competition is not limited to develop-
ing countries. Even the OECD member states suffer from the decline in cor-
porate tax revenues resulting from tax competition because they cannot raise
other taxes, which are already quite high.
54
Instead, most OECD members
had to implement austerity measures that cut the social safety net in the
wake of the financial crisis of 2008, even though they understood the im-
portance of the social safety net for their citizens. For instance, Greece, one
of the European Union (“EU”) members hardest hit by the financial crisis,
was faced with either dramatically raising taxes or drastically curtailing
public health spending, and chose to cut spending, which resulted in under-
staffed and underfunded hospitals and higher copays that drastically impact-
ed vulnerable groups.
55
Similarly, the Netherlands’ financial shortfalls ne-
cessitated a move to privatize insurance companies while Sweden switched
many hospitals and primary health care services over to the private sector
in order to cut costs.
56
These cuts of the social safety net were what led to
the first BEPS Project of the OECD in 2013–15.
57
This BEPS 1.0 Project
was designed to limit tax competition by introducing various measures to
prevent tax base erosion and MNEs shifting profits to low-tax jurisdic-
tions.
58
A major question regarding potential solutions to curbing tax competi-
tion is whether they only address artificial profit shifting to low-tax jurisdic-
tion, such as tax havens, or also target real investment shopping around the
world. The OECD’s Harmful Tax Competition report from 1998 focused on
artificial profit shifting to low-tax jurisdictions, as did the BEPS 1.0 Project,
which was based on the concept of “value creation.”
59
Pillar One of the
global tax deal also focuses on artificial profit shifting. Pillar Two, on the
other hand, addresses both artificial profit shifting and real investment shift-
ing, although the latter is limited only by the substance carve-out described
in Parts III and IV.
54. REVENUE STATISTICS BROCHURE INITIAL IMPACT OF COVID-19 ON OECD TAX
REVENUES, supra note 52, at 9.
55. See Elisavet Athanasia Alexiadou, Health Care Reforms and the Challenge of Ine-
quality From a Human Rights Lens: Lessons From Europe, 17 I
ND.HEALTH L. REV. 63 (2020).
56.Id.at 74.
57. See Reuven Avi-Yonah, The Great Recession and the International Tax Regime,
K
LUWER INTL TAX BLOG (Apr. 23, 2019), http://kluwertaxblog.com/2019/04/23/the-great-
recession-and-the-international-tax-regime.
58. See Itai Grinberg, The New International Tax Diplomacy, 104 G
EO. L.J. 1137
(2016); Transformation, supra note 12, at 354.
59. See Reuven Avi-Yonah, The OECD Harmful Tax Competition Report: A Retro-
spective After a Decade, 34 B
ROOK.J.INTL L. 783 (2009).
516 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
II. EXISTING SOLUTIONS TO TAX COMPETITION
Destructive tax competition would disappear if the international tax re-
gime achieved tax harmony. The difficult part is how to achieve this harmo-
ny. Having a uniform tax system across the globe would be the simplest so-
lution, but it is not realistic when each sovereign country has the ability and
right to develop their own tax systems. Consequently, an international tax
regime should offer a principle and framework that can systematically pre-
vent tax competition if countries agree to participate. This Part introduces
the single tax principle that we endorse and examines the existing efforts to
combat tax competition prior to the Statement and Pillar Two.
A. The Single Tax Principle, 1918 – 2015
The best solution to the problems created by tax competition is the sin-
gle tax principle, which requires that all income of MNEs be subject to taxa-
tion once.
60
However, there is nuance to the single tax principle. If the ef-
fective tax rate for single taxation was nominal, then it would be an empty
solution to resolve tax competition. Thus, to make this principle effective,
the single tax principle accompanies a practical principle—that is, that all
income of MNEs be taxed once at a substantive tax rate, such as the average
G20 tax rate (currently around 26.96 percent).
61
If this proposition is not
met, corrective rules would need to apply to accomplish the result that
MNEs’ income be taxed at a substantive rate.
The income of MNEs’ cross-border transactions involves more than one
country. Thus, the next issue stemming from the single tax principle is
which country should have primary jurisdiction to tax such income. The in-
ternational tax regime answers this question with the benefits principle. The
benefits principle was originally developed in 1923,
62
under which: (1) ac-
tive income from trade or business is primarily assigned to the source coun-
try’s tax jurisdiction (with the residence country having secondary jurisdic-
tion), and (2) passive income, such as dividends, interest, and royalties, is
primarily assigned to the residence country’s tax jurisdiction (with the
source country having secondary jurisdiction).
63
MNEs’ corporate income
from their trade or business is considered active income, and thus, is primar-
ily assigned to source countries where such trade or business is conducted
and income is generated. Because of the primacy of source taxation for ac-
tive income under the benefits principle, residence countries of MNEs that
60.SeeReuven Avi-Yonah, Who Invented the Single Tax Principle?: An Essay on the
History of US Treaty Policy, 59 N.Y.
L. S
CH.L.REV. 305 (2015).
61. See generally Asen, supra note 28. The rate of tax for the single tax principle is the
residence country’s tax rate for passive income (earned mostly by individuals) and the average
G20 source tax rate for active income (earned mostly by corporations).
62. T
HOMAS S. ADAMS,INTERSTATE AND INTERNATIONAL DOUBLE TAXATION,
L
ECTURES ON TAXATION 101 (Roswell Magill ed., 1932).
63.Id.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 517
have secondary tax jurisdiction over such income should grant a foreign tax
credit for source taxes.
64
However, the journey toward achieving the single tax principle encoun-
tered challenges. Globalization in the late twentieth century resulted in in-
creased tax competition among source countries, which are mostly develop-
ing countries with strong needs to lure FDI. Hence, source-based taxation
with a substantive tax rate was difficult to sustain. Furthermore, there are
too many source countries to be able to effectively cooperate to curb tax
competition.
65
The single tax principle solves tax competition among source countries
by requiring a secondary tax jurisdiction to enforce the single tax principle
at a substantive tax rate if source-based taxation is nominal. Such nominal
source taxation should not count as a full “once” for the purposes of the sin-
gle tax principle. Ruth Mason (a Professor of Law and Taxation at the Uni-
versity of Virginia School of Law) refers to this concept as “full taxation.
66
Under the benefits principle, residence countries have secondary tax juris-
diction. If residence countries exercise the secondary tax jurisdiction at a
substantial tax rate, the single tax principle can still be accomplished. This is
relatively straightforward to accomplish compared to an effort to curb
source country tax competition, because over ninety percent of the world’s
largest multinationals are residents of the G20.
67
More importantly, if all residence countries exercise “full taxation”
power on MNEs’ global income, it would eliminate the problem of MNEs
shopping source countries by removing the incentive to do so.
68
If an
MNE’s residence country is going to ensure that the MNE pays its full in-
come tax regardless of the country or tax haven where they claim to have
“earned” the income, there will be no economic benefit for MNEs to source
country shop.
64.SeeMitchell A. Kane, Strategy and Cooperation in National Response to Interna-
tional Tax Arbitrage, 53 E
MORY L.J. 89 (2004) (“Commitment to a single tax principle is in
evidence whenever a country relieves double taxation through a foreign tax credit and will not
agree to tax sparing.”); see also I.R.C. §§ 901, 903.
65.SeeReuven Avi-Yonah and Haiyan Xu, Evaluating BEPS: A Reconsideration of
the Benefits Principle and Proposal for UN Oversight, 6 H
ARV.BUS.L.REV. 185 (2016).
66.Transformation, supra note 12, at 22, 25.
67. Role of the G20, E
UROPEAN COMMN, http://ec.europa.eu/info/food-farming-fisheries
/farming/international-cooperation/international-organisations/g20_en (last visited Mar. 11,
2022); Emmanuel Saez & Gabriel Zucman, A Wealth Taxation on Corporations’ Stock,G20
I
NSIGHTS (2021), http://www.g20-insights.org/policy_briefs/a-wealth-tax-on-corporations-stock/
(“Corporations headquartered in the G20 represent over 90% of global corporate equity mar-
ket value.”).
68. See Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Hanging Together: A Multilateral Approach to Taxing
Multinationals, 5 M
ICH.BUS.&ENTREPRENEURIAL L. REV. 137 (2016).
518 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
1. The Origins of the Single Tax Principle
The origins of the single tax principle can be traced back to the adop-
tion of the U.S. foreign tax credit in 1918.
69
Double taxation occurs in inter-
national tax when a source country and residence country levy tax on the
same declared income.
70
Many countries enter into income tax treaties to
avoid such double taxation. Under such tax treaties, source countries offer
reduced withholding tax rates for aliens’ income from domestic sources,
whereas residence countries offer tax exemption or credit to foreign-source
income.
71
Thomas Adams, the U.S. Treasury advisor who introduced the
credit, stated that he rejected the exemption system used by most European
countries because it led to double non-taxation.
72
The same formulation can be found in the commentary to the first mod-
el tax treaty, issued under the auspices of the League of Nations in 1927,
which states as follows:
It is highly desirable that States should come to an agreement with
a view to ensuring that a taxpayer shall not be taxed on the same
income by a number of different countries, and it seems equally de-
sirable that such international cooperation should prevent certain
incomes from escaping taxation altogether. The most elementary
and undisputed principles of fiscal justice, therefore, required that
the experts should devise a scheme whereby all incomes would be
taxed once and only once.
73
American tax policy began to change in the 1960s under the guidance
of Stanley Surrey, the first Assistant Secretary for Tax Policy and the true
intellectual father of the single tax principle. Surrey had publicly advocated
for the single tax principle in 1957 when he testified in the U.S. Senate
against a proposed United States-Pakistan tax treaty that provided for dou-
ble non-taxation.
74
The treaty was not ratified. Surrey proposed imposing
69. See Avi-Yonah, supra note 60.
70.SeeKlaus Vogel, Double Tax Treaties and Their Interpretation, 4 B
ERKELEY J.
I
NTL L. 4 (1986).
71. See C
HARLES H. GUSTAFSON,ROBERT J. PERONI &RICHARD CRAWFORD PUGH,
T
AXATION OF INTERNATIONAL TRANSACTIONS:MATERIALS,TEXT, AND PROBLEMS 63 (4th
ed. 2011).
72. A
DAMS, supra note 62, at 101, 112–13. For example, the first U.S. tax treaty with
France in 1932 abolished the United States withholding tax on royalties despite the fact that
France would not tax them, thereby creating certain double non-taxation in violation of the
single tax principle.
73. Reports Presented by the Comm. of Technical Experts on Double Taxation and Tax
Evasion, League of Nations Doc. C.216M.85 1927 II (1927). The first model tax treaty also
included a provision imposing a withholding tax on interest, but provided that it would be re-
funded if the taxpayer could show that the income was declared to her country of residence.
74. Joseph J. Thorndike, Stanley Surrey Knew a Thing or Two About Loopholes,T
AX
ANALYSTS ARTICLE ARCHIVE ONLINE (Feb. 7, 2013), http://www.taxhistory.org/thp
/readings.nsf/ArtWeb/05B6E5635C931F6F85257B160048DD4D?OpenDocument.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 519
U.S. taxation in full on all Controlled Foreign Companies (“CFCs”)
75
of
U.S. MNEs. Although Subpart F enacted in 1962 only applied the tax in sit-
uations where the income was likely to escape source taxation,
76
Surrey
achieved his main aim of generally imposing the single tax principle on U.S.
MNEs. Surrey also incorporated the single tax principle into U.S. tax trea-
ties (for example, the United States-Luxembourg tax treaty)
77
by making it
clear that U.S. withholding taxes would not be reduced unless the income
was subject to tax in the residence jurisdiction.
78
This provision was also
included in the first U.S. Model Tax Treaty of 1981.
79
In the same year, however, the United States succumbed to the pres-
sures of globalization and the need to attract foreign investment by enacting
the portfolio interest exemption, which abolished the U.S. withholding tax
on portfolio interest regardless of whether it was taxed at the source.
80
The
rule violated the single tax principle, but also led to massive capital flight
into the United States. It is one of the first examples of U.S. tax competition
during globalization.
81
Furthermore, in the 1990s, Congress began weaken-
ing Subpart F by adopting exceptions, such as for active banking and insur-
ance, even though the income was mobile and not taxed at the source.
82
The erosion of the single tax principle culminated with the establish-
ment in 1997 of the “check the box” rule, which led to the complete under-
mining of Subpart F, especially after it was codified in 2006.
83
The “check
75. I.R.C. §§ 957(a), 951, 952; Controlled Foreign Corporations (“CFCs”) are foreign
corporations in which more than fifty percent of the vote or value is owned by U.S. sharehold-
ers who each own ten percent or more of the CFC.
76. I.R.C. §§ 951–65; The Subpart F provisions of the Internal Revenue Code eliminate
deferral of U.S. tax on some categories of foreign income by taxing certain U.S. persons cur-
rently on their pro rata share of such income earned by their CFCs.
77. Income and Capital Tax Treaty, Lux.-U.S., art. XVI, Dec. 18, 1962, http://
www.irs.gov/pub/irs-trty/luxem.pdf.
78. This is the origin of the Subject to Tax Rule (“STTR”) in Pillar Two, discussed in-
fra Part III.A.2.
79. Single Tax Principle, supra note 12; Reuven Avi-Yonah & Gianluca Mazzoni,
Stanley Surrey, the 1981 US Model, and the Single Tax Principle, 49 I
NTERTAX 729 (2021).
In 1984, the United States terminated its treaties with tax havens such as the Netherlands An-
tilles because they led to double non taxation in violation of the single tax principle.
80. I.R.C. § 871(h)(3); see Marilyn Franson, Repeal of the Thirty Percent Withholding
Tax on Portfolio Interest Paid to Foreign Investors, 6 N
W. J. INTL L. & BUS. 3 (1984).
81. Reuven Avi-Yonah, What Goes Around Comes Around: Why the USA is Responsi-
ble for Capital Flight (and What It Can Do About It), 13
HAIFA L. REV. 321 (2019).
82. D
AVID R. SICULAR, THE NEW LOOK-THROUGH RULE: W(H)ITHER SUBPART F?
(Apr. 23, 2007), http://www.paulweiss.com/media/104725/SubPartF04-May-07.pdf.
83. A business entity may be treated as a pass-through entity (such as partnership or
disregarded entity) or a corporation for U.S. income tax purposes. Prior to the entity classifi-
cation regulations (also known as the “check-the-box”), an entity’s tax classification as a cor-
poration or flow-through entity was determined by a multifactor text. However, the check-the-
box regulations enacted in 1997 allow an eligible (i.e., not automatically classified as a corpo-
520 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
the box” rule enables U.S. MNEs to shift income from both the United
States and high-tax foreign countries to tax havens without triggering Sub-
part F.
84
The result of this erosion and violation of the single tax principle
was that, by 2017, U.S. MNEs had amassed more than $3 trillion USD of
income in low-tax foreign jurisdictions.
85
Due to the increasingly intense and competitive nature of tax competi-
tion between countries over the past twenty-five years, the first author of
this article, Reuven Avi-Yonah, has advocated for the single tax principle as
a solution to tax competition since 1997.
86
Income from cross-border trans-
actions should be subject to one-time taxation. However, taxing cross-
border income just once also means care should be taken that it should not
be undertaxed. With this in mind, Avi-Yonah has argued that the appropri-
ate rate of tax for purposes of the single tax principle would be determined
by the second principle of international taxation, the benefits principle. That
means the active income should be taxed at least at the source tax rate
(which tends to be lower than the residence rate), but at no more than the
residence rate.
As Part III demonstrates, the underlying idea behind Pillar Two can be
traced back to the concept of the single tax principle.
87
Specifically, Pillar
Two offers various measures by which residual taxation by the residence (or
source) jurisdiction should occur when the tax imposed by the source (or
ration) entity to elect to be classified as a corporate or a pass-through for U.S. income tax pur-
poses. I.R.C. § 7701; Treas. Reg. § 301.7701-2; see also S
ICULAR, supra note 82.
84.Id.
85. Richard Phillips, Matt Gardner, Alexandria Robins & Michelle Surka, Offshore
Shell Games 2017,I
NST. ON TAXN &ECON.POLY (Oct. 17, 2017), http://itep.org/off
shoreshellgames2017.
86. Reuven Avi-Yonah, International Taxation of Electronic Commerce, 52 T
AX L.
R
EV. 507 (1997) [hereinafter, Electronic Commerce]. Avi-Yonah later developed a different
normative argument for the single tax principle, basing it for corporate taxation on the need to
curb the power of the largest multinationals. See Reuven Avi-Yonah, Corporations, Society
and the State: A Defense of the Corporate Tax, 90 V
A.L.REV. 1193, 1202 (2004); Reuven
Avi-Yonah, A New Corporate Tax,T
AX NOTES FED. 653, 654 (2020).
87. This similarity has been noted by other scholars. See, e.g., Elizabeth Gil García,
The Single Tax Principle: Fiction or Reality in a Non-Comprehensive International Tax Re-
gime? 11 W
ORLD TAX J. 497 (2019); Transformation, supra note 12, at 353 (“Because states
already faithfully adhered to the no-double-tax norm, growing acceptance of full taxation as a
goal of international tax brings states closer to implementing Avi-Yonah’s “single-tax princi-
ple.”); Leopoldo Parada, Full Taxation: The Single Tax Emperor’s New Clothes, 24 F
LA.TAX
REV. 729 (2021) (identifying the BEPS 2.0 project (consisting of Pillars One and Two) as a
modern approach to the single tax principle); Wolfgang Schoen, Is There Finally an Interna-
tional Tax System? in T
HINKER,TEACHER,TRAVELER:REIMAGINING INTERNATIONAL TAX,
E
SSAYS IN HONOR OF H. DAVID ROSENBLOOM 475 (Georg Kofler et al. eds., IBFD 2021)
(“What can one say about the “single tax principle”? Has it gained the status of a guiding and
binding principle of international tax law? Here, it is evident that the BEPS Action Plan
adopted Avi-Yonah’s findings to a large extent. International taxation – it claims – should
ensure that income from cross-border transactions is taxed exactly once – not more, not
less.”).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 521
residence) jurisdiction falls below a specified level—that is, the global min-
imum tax rate. Such mechanic embodies the idea of corrective measures to
prevent insufficient taxation as argued by the first author of this article in
support of the single tax principle.
88
2. Academic Debate
Scholars and commentators have engaged in a long debate on whether
tax harmony or achieving the single tax principle would be possible in the
real world. H. David Rosenbloom of New York University, in his famous
Tillinghast Lecture in 1998,
89
characterized international tax arbitrage as
“the deliberate exploitation of differences in national tax systems.”
90
To
Rosenbloom, international tax harmony was an unachievable ideal, whereas
tax competition and the resulting arbitrage was an inevitable by-product of
independent tax policymaking by sovereign states. Thus, preventing mis-
matches in tax policy “is not and should not be a first-rank policy objective
of the United States.
91
Rosenbloom also identified line-drawing problems
related to distinguishing impermissible arbitrage from permissible tax plan-
ning. Rosenbloom considered “international income” and the “international
tax system” to be imaginary, rejected the single tax principle, and thus, ar-
gued that there was no principled objection to arbitrage.
92
Academics, including the first author of this article, responded to Ros-
enbloom’s critique by clarifying the policy concerns raised by international
tax competition and tax arbitrage and further detailing the efficiencies and
benefits of the single tax principle.
93
Adam Rosenzweig
94
and Diane Ring
95
88. Electronic Commerce, supra note 86, at 517.
89. H. David Rosenbloom, The David R. Tillinghast Lecture International Tax Arbi-
trage and the “International Tax System, 53 T
AX L. REV. 137, 137 (2000) [hereinafter, Arbi-
trage]; Reuven Avi-Yonah, Commentary on Rosenbloom, 53 T
AX L. REV. 167, 167 (2000);
Michael J. Graetz, Taxing International Income - Inadequate Principles, Outdated Concepts,
and Unsatisfactory Policy, 54 T
AX L. REV. 261, 335 (2001); DANIEL SHAVIRO,FIXING US
I
NTERNATIONAL TAXATION 2 (2014), http://web.law.columbia.edu/sites/default/files/microsites
/law-theory-workshop/files/DShaviro.pdf; Julie Roin, Taxation Without Coordination, 31 J.
L
EGAL STUD. S61, S61 (2002); see Kane, supra note 64, at 92; Yariv Brauner, An Interna-
tional Tax Regime in Crystallization,56
T
AX L. REV. 259, 262–63. For a summary of the aca-
demic debate, see Ruth Mason & Pascal Saint-Amans, Has Cross-Border Arbitrage Met Its
Match?, in T
HINKER,TEACHER,TRAVELER:REIMAGINING INTERNATIONAL TAX.ESSAYS IN
HONOR OF H. DAVID ROSENBLOOM (Georg Kofler et al. eds., IBFD 2021), reprinted in 41
V
A.TAX REV. 1, 10–11 (2021).
90.Arbitrage, supra note 89, at 166. Recently, the term “mismatches” has been more
often used to describe arbitrage.
91. H. David Rosenbloom, Cross-Border Arbitrage: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly,
85 T
AXES 115, 116 (2007).
92.Id. at 115.
93. Avi-Yonah, supra note 89, at 170–71.
94. Adam H. Rosenzweig, Harnessing the Costs of International Tax Arbitrage, 26 V
A.
T
AX REV. 555, 564–65 (2007).
522 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
argued that international tax competition and the resulting arbitrage raised
equity concerns because not everyone could benefit from it. Daniel Shaviro,
Mitchell Kane, Ring, and Rosenzweig highlighted the efficiency concerns,
arguing that tax competition and the resulting arbitrage could cause various
behavioral responses of taxpayers, such as distorting the choice of location
for investment.
96
Some commentators were concerned about the interaction effect that
could arise from U.S. tax policy responses to arbitrage. Shaviro pointed out
that a unilateral response may cause retaliation by other countries.
97
Kane
developed a model involving zero-sum tax competition among states seek-
ing to attract capital and argued that a state might exploit the ambiguity of
mismatching tax rules to win this competition without instigating retaliatory
responses.
98
Omri Marian’s study of the LuxLeaks rulings demonstrated
how the country Luxembourg was able to exploit the mismatches/arbitrages
of tax rules in such a way as to gain a significant economic advantage over
its neighboring states without attracting notice.
99
Rosenbloom also pushed back on the notion that tax competition and
arbitrage was a threat to revenue. He argued that as long as the taxpayer
complies with each national tax regime, no one country has cause to com-
plain about revenue loss.
100
Kane and Rosenbloom rejected the conception
of hypothetical, collective income, or revenue that could have been availa-
ble had tax competition not existed.
101
However, the over 170 member ju-
risdictions of the BEPS Inclusive Framework who signed on to the State-
ment and Pillar Two clearly disagree.
102
95.SeeDiane M. Ring, One Nation Among Many: Policy Implications of Cross-Border
Tax Arbitrage, 44 B.C.
L. R
EV. 79, 125–28 (2002).
96. Daniel Shaviro, Money on the Table?: Responding to Cross-Border Tax Arbitrage,
3C
HI.J.INTL L. 317, 323–25 (2002); Kane, supra note 64, at 114; Ring, supra note 95, at
126–27 (2002); Rosenzweig, supra note 94, at 564–65.
97. Shaviro, supra note 96, at 327.
98. Kane, supra note 64, at 142.
99. Until national legislators and the European Commission began to uncover the Lux-
embourg’s secret tax ruling practice to offer favorable tax treatment, there had been no retalia-
tion from other European Union (“EU”) countries because they simply did not know about it.
See Omri Marian, The State Administration of International Tax Avoidance, 7 H
ARV.BUS.L.
R
EV. 1, 27–28 (2017).
100. Avi-Yonah, supra note 89, at 167.
101. Mason & Saint-Amans, supra note 89, at 5; see Kane, supra note 64, at 115 (argu-
ing that the acceptance of the single tax principle suggests that there is some international
consensus on the meaning of income, but no such consensus exists.).
102. OECD, H
YBRID MISMATCH ARRANGEMENTS:TAX POLICY AND COMPLIANCE
ISSUES 11 (2012), http://www.oecd.org/ctp/exchange-of-tax-information/hybrid-mismatch-
arrangements-tax-policy-and-compliance-issues.pdf (“Although it is often difficult to deter-
mine which of countries involved has lost tax revenue [as a result of tax competition], it is
clear that collectively the countries concerned lose tax revenue.”).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 523
On a more direct challenge to the single tax principle, scholars have
raised concerns about what it means to tax only once.
103
Shaviro suggests
that being taxed twice at low rates (for example, two percent and two per-
cent) need not necessarily be worse than being taxed once (for example, five
percent).
104
He further argues that the single tax principle would be hard to
operationalize despite higher levels of international cooperation because it is
“challenging to coordinate distinctive tax systems across multiple complex
dimensions” and, worse, countries have little interest in harmonizing their
tax rules.
105
Nevertheless, recent developments, such as 137 Inclusive Framework
member jurisdictions agreeing to the two-Pillar solution—including the
global minimum tax in the Statement
106
—indicate that international interest
in tax harmony is not as outlandish as some scholars suggest.
107
But the
global tax deal in the Statement was not built in a day. The next subpart fur-
ther explains the global reaction toward the single tax principle and tax
harmony prior to the creation of Pillar Two.
B. Global Efforts Begin in the Late 2000s
The recent international struggle in combatting tax competition is well
known among those in the field of international taxation. The first promis-
ing step toward the single tax principle occurred in the context of tax infor-
mation transparency. Following the 2008 financial crisis, the Foreign Ac-
count Tax Compliance Act of 2010 (“FATCA”) was enacted in the United
States.
108
FATCA was designed to stop the practice of U.S. residents pre-
tending to be foreigners in order to escape from U.S. taxation.
109
This prac-
103. John Bentil, Situating the International Tax System Within Public International
Law, 49 G
EO.J.INTL L. 1219, 1251–52 (2018); see also Daniel Shaviro, The Two Faces of
the Single Tax Principle, 41 B
ROOK.J.INTL L. 1293, 1294 (2016).
104. Shaviro, supra note 103, at 1294. However, this argument did not consider that tax-
ing once in the single tax principle has more nuance than just one count—that is, cross-border
income should be taxed once at a substantive tax rate.
105. Daniel Shaviro, The Crossroads Versus the Seesaw: Getting a “Fix” on Recent
International Tax Policy Developments, 69 T
AX L. REV. 1, 3–4 (2015).
106.Statement, supra note 1, at 4–5.
107.SeeBentil, supra note 103, at 1251–52; Shaviro, supra note 96, at 330 (arguing the
STP would be difficult to operationalize despite increased levels of international cooperation
because “[s]hort of countries agreeing to harmonize their distinctive rules (which they appear
to have little interest in doing), it is quite challenging to coordinate all of the interactions be-
tween distinctive systems across multiple complex dimensions.”).
108. See, e.g., Michael S. Kirsch, Revisiting the Tax Treatment of Citizens Abroad: Rec-
onciling Principle and Practice, 16 F
LA.TAX REV. 117, 122 (2014).
109. To explain this concept more technically, U.S. residents pretend to be foreigners to
enjoy tax benefit from the portfolio interest exemption and other tax breaks for foreign portfo-
lio investment, such as the exemption of capital gains. For an explanation of FATCA general-
ly, see Young Ran (Christine) Kim, Considering “Citizenship Taxation”: In Defense of
FATCA, 20 F
LA.TAX REV. 335, 359–62 (2017).
524 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
tice enabled double non-taxation of income hidden in offshore accounts,
where such assets were rarely detected because of bank secrecy.
110
Thus,
FATCA required foreign financial institutions, such as Swiss banks, to re-
port accounts held by U.S. residents and citizens to the U.S. government.
111
If foreign financial institutions do not comply, they are subject to tax penal-
ties and criminal charges. FATCA’s major success directly led to the devel-
opment of the Common Reporting Standard at the global level, which linked
over 100 foreign jurisdictions in a system where they could automatically
exchange tax information with each other.
112
The enhanced transparency in
tax information among countries can help achieve the single tax principle
because it prevents double non-taxation of passive investment income
earned by individuals. It is still not perfect (as evidenced by the recent leaks,
such as the Pandora Papers),
113
but it is a significant step forward to full im-
plementation of the single tax principle.
Second, in recent years, many countries have been more willing to co-
operate and harmonize substantive tax rules to resolve tax competition.
114
In
Europe, the 2008 financial crisis led to massive austerity, which in turn put
pressure on politicians to raise concerns that MNEs (especially U.S. MNEs)
were not paying their fair share of tax to Europe as a source jurisdiction.
115
Some countries, such as the United Kingdom and France, realized that tradi-
tional international tax rules with a physical presence requirement did not
allow them to tax Big Tech despite the fact that those companies collected
and profited from the user data of their citizens.
116
Thus, they adopted digi-
tal services taxes (“DSTs”).
117
This move caused heated debate around the
world, leading the OECD to launch BEPS Project 1.0 to try to update the
international tax regime that overlooked under-taxation of the digital econ-
omy and to prevent trade wars over individually-enacted DSTs.
118
Through these efforts, countries realized that a complete harmonization
of substantive tax law was unlikely to be fully successful as a comprehen-
110.Id.
111. I.R.C. §§ 1471, 1472, 1473, 1474.
112. See id.
113. See The Pandora Papers: An ICIJ Investigation, I
NTL CONSORTIUM INDEP.
J
OURNALISTS http://www.icij.org/investigations/pandora-papers/ (last visited Mar. 11, 2022).
The Pandora Papers are 11.9 million leaked documents that the International Consortium of
Investigative Journalists published that exposed the secret offshore accounts of thirty-five
world leaders as well as more than 100 billionaires, celebrities and business leaders
114.SeeOECD,
I
NCLUSIVE FRAMEWORK ON BASE EROSION AND PROFIT SHIFTING,
http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/ (last visited Mar. 11, 2022).
115.SeeSchreuer Rappepert & Singer Tankersley, Europes Planned Digital Tax
Heightens Tensions with US, N.Y.
T
IMES, Mar. 19, 2018, at 1–2, http://www.nytimes.com
/2018/03/19/us/politics/europe-digital-tax-trade.html.
116.Id. at 34.
117. See e.g., Young Ran (Christine) Kim, Digital Services Tax: A Cross-border Varia-
tion of the Consumption Tax Debate, 72 A
LA.L.REV. 131, 136 (2020).
118. OECD, supra note 114.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 525
sive solution to tax competition because individual states would be reluctant
to defer to another states’ underlying tax rules, or agree to implement a
common set of rules for harmonization that may not match their tax objec-
tives.
119
An alternative to harmonization that states have pursued recently
are conditional rules.
120
Mason explains these conditional rules as “fiscal
fail-safe” measures to guarantee full taxation and implement the single tax
principle.
121
In other words, the conditional or secondary rules attempt to
ensure that cross-border income does not escape tax by identifying “condi-
tions under which, if one country does not tax, another country fills the tax
void.”
122
These conditional rules emerged in the BEPS Project 1.0, such as
in Action 3 for expanding the CFC regimes
123
and Action 2 for anti-hybrid
rules.
124
The BEPS Project 2.0 Pillar Two for a global minimum tax is also
built on this conditional, fiscal fail-safe rules as demonstrated in Part
III.A.
125
Although not extensively harmonious because of various carve-
outs and specific exceptions that various countries demanded, the examples
reflect a new willingness to cooperatively coordinate efforts to address in-
ternational tax arbitrage in a more comprehensive way.
On reflection, BEPS Project 1.0 included some significant steps toward
tax harmony and the single tax principle. BEPS Project 1.0 is contrary to
Rosenbloom’s preferred solution of acquiescing to tax competition and arbi-
trage, which is doing nothing, because he did not believe there was a prob-
lem to solve. However, while this Project advanced the single tax principle,
most of its actions have been recommendations, not requirements, and for
the most part its recommendations went unimplemented throughout the
world. However, the EU did adopt various action items of BEPS Project 1.0
through its own directives, such as the Anti-Tax Avoidance Directive
(“ATAD).
126
But such a regional approach is limited in its ability to ad-
vance the single tax principle because of the need for global harmonization.
BEPS Project 1.0 was disappointing because it did not fully implement the
119. See e.g., Yariv Brauner, Treaties in the Aftermath of BEPS, 41 BROOK.J.INTL L.
974, 976–77 (2016).
120. See Transformation, supra note 12, at 378–79. Mason offers two examples of con-
ditional rules: penalty defaults and fiscal fail-safes. Penalty defaults may be set up in tax law
and treaties if states do not resolve tax ambiguities against the taxpayer. Rules that deny tax-
treaty benefits to fiscally transparent entities could be understood as penalty defaults. Fiscal
fail safes are explained in the above text.
121.Id.at 374–75.
122.Id.at 381.
123. OECD, D
ESIGNING EFFECTIVE CONTROLLED FOREIGN COMPANY RULES,ACTION
3–2015FINAL REPORT 12 (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241152-en.
124. OECD, N
EUTRALISING THE EFFECTS OF HYBRID MISMATCH ARRANGEMENTS,
A
CTION 2 – 2015 FINAL REPORT 49–50 (2015), http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241138-en.
125. See infra Part III.A.
126. Reuven Avi-Yonah & Gianluca Mazzoni, BEPS, ATAP and the New Tax Dialogue:
A Transatlantic Competition? 46
I
NTERTAX 885, 885 (2018).
526 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
single tax principle on any meaningful scale or update the international tax
regime for the twenty-first century.
127
The shortcomings of BEPS Project 1.0 were addressed in BEPS Project
2.0. The new project developed a plan for international taxation that ad-
dressed the most pressing concerns in the plan’s two Pillars. However, the
impetus of the plan did not come from the EU or any other multilateral
agreement – it was a direct result of the passage of the TCJA. The next sub-
part discusses the important provisions of the TCJA that inspired BEPS Pro-
ject. 2.0.
C. The TCJA as Constructive Unilateralism
The United States has a long history of unilaterally adopting tax poli-
cies that are later enacted by many other countries around the world. This
risk-taking on the part of the United States is considered by many to be in-
ternationally constructive because it allows other jurisdictions to evaluate
the effectiveness of a tax policy before implementation.
128
Most notably, the
United States has led the way with the Foreign Tax Credit, CFCs, and the
two international tax rules in the TCJA—GILTI and BEAT, discussed in
more detail below.
129
Passage of the TCJA was not primarily motivated by a desire to imple-
ment the single tax principle. Instead, the U.S. government wanted to bring
back and tax the nearly $3 trillion USD of offshore corporate profits of the
U.S. MNEs.
130
Before the TCJA, U.S. parent companies with foreign sub-
sidiaries were generally not taxed on the earnings of their subsidiaries until
the earnings were distributed to them (or repatriated to the United States).
131
If the foreign corporation did not distribute earnings back to the United
States, U.S. parents could indefinitely defer paying U.S. taxes at the thirty-
five percent rate on this foreign income.
132
As a result, U.S. MNEs, such as
Apple, could incorporate a subsidiary in tax havens or low-tax jurisdictions
like Ireland (where the corporate tax rate is 12.5 percent) and allocate as
127. Reuven Avi-Yonah, Full Circle: The Single Tax Principle, BEPS, and the New US
Model, 1G
LOBAL TAXN 12, 12 (2016) (criticizing BEPS Project 1.0 for not changing the
obsolete physical presence requirement in tax treaties and limiting the unworkable arm’s
length standard for transfer pricing).
128. Reuven Avi-Yonah, Constructive Dialogue: BEPA and the TCJA 2 (Univ. Mich.
Pub. L.
Rsch. Paper No. 665, 2020), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=
3544065.).
129.Id.at 2, 4, 16.
130. Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, The International Provisions of the TCJA: A Preliminary
Summary and Assessment, (Univ. Mich. Pub. L. Rsch. Paper No. 605, 2017), http://
papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3193278.
131.Id.
132. Upon repatriation of earnings from a foreign subsidiary, U.S. corporate sharehold-
ers’ earnings were treated as dividends that were included in the parent corporation’s income
and were subject to U.S. taxation at a rate of up to thirty-five percent with a foreign tax credit
based on foreign taxes paid.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 527
much taxable income as possible to these low-tax jurisdictions in order to
minimize U.S. corporate income tax.
133
Between 2005 and 2017, U.S.
MNEs had accumulated $2.6 trillion USD of low-taxed foreign income off-
shore that had never been subject to the thirty-five percent corporate income
tax rate.
134
Thus, one of the primary goals of the TCJA was to remove po-
tential tax benefits from offshoring income, thus returning the $2.6 trillion
USD in capital to the United States for taxation and deterring such profit-
shifting activity in the future.
135
At the same time, other corporations whose businesses are more fo-
cused on the domestic market, such as Walmart, lobbied to reduce the thir-
ty-five percent corporate tax rate, while owners of pass-through entities
(like then-President Trump) pushed for a reduction of the tax rate on part-
nerships.
136
The result was the TCJA. The TCJA implemented a participation ex-
emption for dividends from CFCs,
137
cut the corporate tax rate from thirty-
five percent to twenty-one percent,
138
and cut the partnership and other
pass-through tax rate from thirty-seven percent to 29.6 percent.
139
However,
to pay for all these tax cuts within the confines of Budget Reconciliation,
the Republican members of Congress decided to apply the single tax princi-
ple to U.S. MNEs to stop their base erosion and profit-shifting strategies
that have harmed U.S. revenue.
140
Three important provisions of the TCJA represented steps toward the
single tax principle. First is the one-time mandatory “repatriation tax”
(sometimes referred to as the “transition tax”). A significant tax rate (be-
133. For example, in a recent high-profile tax case, the European Commission demanded
that Apple pay Ireland €13.1 billion Euros in underpaid taxes because Ireland granted state aid
to the company. Padraic Halpin, Ireland Collects Disputed Apple Taxes in Full ahead of Ap-
peal,R
EUTERS (Sept. 18, 2018, 8:55 AM), http://reut.rs/38wQSLQ.
134. Key Elements of the U.S. Tax System,T
AX POLY CTR. (last updated May 2020),
http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/briefing-book/what-tcja-repatriation-tax-and-how-does-it-
work.
135. See Avi-Yonah, supra note 130.
136.SeeJohn Ydstie, How Trump’s Corporate Tax Cut Is Playing Out for Wal-Mart,
NPR (Jan. 13, 2018, 5:47 PM), http://www.npr.org/2018/01/13/577900650/how-trump-s-
corporate-tax-cut-is-playing-out-with-wal-mart; see also Reuven Avi-Yonah, How Terrible is
the New Tax Law? Reflections on TRA17, (Univ. of Mich. Pub. L. Rsch. Paper No. 586,
2018), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3095830.
137. Before the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (“TCJA”), U.S. taxpayers were subject to U.S.
income taxes on their worldwide income. But income earned by the foreign subsidiaries of
U.S. corporations was subject to tax only when repatriated to the United States as dividends.
The TCJA changed the tax rules for multinational corporations by generally exempting the
earnings of foreign subsidiaries’ active businesses from U.S. corporate taxation, even if repat-
riated. Technically, there now is a 100 percent dividend-received deduction. This is called
“participation exemption.” I.R.C. § 245A.
138. I.R.C. § 11.
139. I.R.C. § 199A.
140.SeeAvi-Yonah, supra note 136, at 5–6.
528 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
tween eight and fifteen percent) was imposed on the past accumulated off-
shore profits of U.S. MNEs.
141
It was imposed only one time, and it did not
matter whether those offshore profits were repatriated to the United
States.
142
Those profits were parked in low-tax jurisdictions, resulting in
nominal source taxation. They were not subject to residence taxation by the
United States because the pre-TCJA tax law allowed the U.S. MNEs to de-
fer taxation until the profits were repatriated.
143
Hence, the new temporary
repatriation tax in the TCJA implemented the single tax principle because
these profits were previously subject to double non-taxation through the
“check the box” policy.
Second, the GILTI rule imposed a tax on certain foreign subsidiaries’
income from intangible assets.
144
Although the TCJA lowered the top cor-
porate income tax rate from thirty-five percent to a flat twenty-one percent,
the U.S. corporate tax rate still exceeds the rate in many countries.
145
Thus,
situating ownership of a profitable patent, for example, in a foreign subsidi-
ary in a lower-rate or no-tax jurisdiction instead of in the United States still
could produce a substantial tax savings for an MNE. GILTI aims to prevent
such profit shifting from easily movable intangible assets by imposing the
U.S. tax as residence taxation on foreign-source income from intangibles.
146
GILTI is foreign income earned by U.S. shareholders of CFCs from intan-
gible assets, such as copyrights, trademarks, and patents. It is calculated as
the total active income earned by a CFC that exceeds ten percent of the
firm’s depreciable tangible property (known as the Qualified Business Asset
Investment, or “QBAI”). The resulting U.S. shareholders who own ten per-
cent or more of a CFC are liable for the tax on its GILTI, which generally
applies at a rate between 10.5 percent and 13.125 percent.
147
GILTI is per-
haps the most successful and influential achievement of the single tax prin-
ciple contained within the TCJA. Income subject to the GILTI rule would
be subject to little-to-no tax in source and otherwise not be subject to U.S.
141. I.R.C. § 965.
142.SeeReuven Avi-Yonah, The International Provisions of the TCJA: Six Results Af-
ter Six Months (Univ. of Mich. Pub. L. Rsch. Paper No. 621, 2018), http://papers.ssrn.com
/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3242008.
143. U.S. multinational enterprises (“MNEs”) deployed complicated corporate structures
with the check-the-box rule so that they could defer the U.S. taxation until the offshore profits
were repatriated, which rarely happened.
144. See Avi-Yonah, supra note 142.
145.Id.
146.Id.;Avi-Yonah, The Baby and the Bathwater: Reflections on the TCJA’s Interna-
tional Provisions, 101 T
AX NOTES INTL 599 (Feb. 1, 2021).
147. I.R.C. § 951A. Under current law, GILTI is defined as net foreign income after a
deduction for 10 ten percent of the value of foreign tangible assets. Half of GILTI is taxed at
the U.S. corporate rate of twenty one percent, which means the basic rate on GILTI is 10.5%.
If a company pays foreign taxes, it can claim eighty percent of the value of those taxes as a
credit against GILTI liability. Taking this foreign tax credit policy into account means the tax
rate on GILTI moves up to 13.125%.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 529
residence taxation. The exclusion for offshore tangible assets returns (the
QBAI exemption) may tarnish the purpose of GILTI, but it is unlikely to be
a major drawback because the largest U.S. MNEs had few tangible assets
offshore.
148
Finally, the BEAT provision addressed the problem of base erosion by
foreign MNEs.
149
Suppose that a U.S. corporation pays deductible pay-
ments, such as interest and royalties, to a related foreign entity. From the
foreign entity’s perspective, such interest and royalties are U.S. source in-
come. But suppose further that the foreign entity is not subject to U.S. with-
holding tax for various reasons, such as tax treaty benefits and statutory tax
exemptions. This is a classic example of multinationals escaping source-
based taxation (in this case, U.S. taxation) by accumulating large amounts
of deductible payments offshore. Neither the U.S. corporation nor the for-
eign recipient pay tax to the source country. To avoid such base-erosion
payment, the BEAT reverses deductions and imposes an alternative mini-
mum tax set at ten percent (12.5 percent from 2026) on the modified tax
base of the U.S. corporation.
150
The BEAT was enacted despite potentially
violating the non-discrimination provision of all U.S. tax treaties because
the rule applies to the case of “U.S. subsidiary-foreign parent” but not the
case of “U.S. subsidiary-U.S. parent.
151
Nonetheless, BEAT effectively
denies deductions in source countries for payments that are unlikely to be
subject to residence-based taxation. BEAT achieves the single tax principle
by strengthening source-based taxation.
The TCJA, albeit begrudgingly, moved the United States toward the
single tax principle and combating tax competition. The global result was
remarkably constructive, as the TCJA demonstrated a means to feasibly
achieve reasonable tax harmonization. Inspired by the international tax pro-
visions of the TCJA, the G20 and the OECD launched BEPS Project 2.0 in
2017, using GILTI and BEAT as the models for its Pillar Two proposal. Pil-
lar One of the Statement focuses on updating outdated rules in source-based
taxation.
152
Pillar Two is more directly on point for implementing the single
tax principle through a combination of rules strengthening residence-based
taxation (for example, the IIR) and source-based taxation (UTPR and
STTR). The benchmark of “substantial tax” counted “once” for single tax
148. This also meant that the new participation exemption in the TCJA violates the sin-
gle tax principle, but it is unlikely to benefit the multinationals much.
149. I.R.C. § 59A.
150.Id.
151. A tax treaty’s non-discrimination provision promises to treat nationals of one coun-
try that is party to the tax treaty the same as nationals of the source country that is party to the
tax treaty if both sets of nationals are in the same circumstance. Under BEAT, it is possible
that two corporations in the same circumstance could be treated differently.
152. Pillar One focuses on source-based taxation and finally partially abolishes the obso-
lete physical presence requirement and the arm’s length standard for some of the profits of
large multinationals above a fixed return on assets. See Avi-Yonah, Kim & Sam, supra note 4.
530 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
purposes is set at fifteen percent, the global minimum tax. Part III will dis-
cuss Pillar Two in greater detail.
III. A NEW SOLUTION:PILLAR TWO AND GLOBAL MINIMUM TAX
The Statement presents Pillar Two and the global minimum tax as a
new solution to tax competition. Together with Pillar One, the entire
framework in the Statement represents a revolution in international taxation
by offering many solutions, such as eliminating the obsolete permanent es-
tablishment requirement for Amount A in Pillar One and proposing a fifteen
percent global minimum tax in Pillar Two. All of these are decisive breaks
from the past, and have been suggested for twenty-five years but have
gained little traction until now.
153
Thus, the Statement encompasses both
revolution and evolution.
This Part focuses on Pillar Two of the Statement. Pillar Two is a new
solution to tax competition. It is aimed at systematically preventing the race
to the bottom and eliminating incentives for both states and MNEs to en-
gage in tax competition. However, this novel solution builds upon past ef-
forts. This article argues that Pillar Two has finally embodied the single tax
principle which states that all income of MNEs ought to be taxed once at a
substantive tax rate. If this proposition is not met, corrective rules apply to
accomplish the result. This Part explains the details of Pillar Two and the
relevant implementation rules, such as the proposed BBB Act of the United
States. The rules are very technical and complex. Evaluating these rules
through the lens of the single tax principle—that all income must be taxed
once substantially—will help readers understand the rules intuitively if the
technicalities overwhelm.
A. Unpacking Pillar Two
Pillar Two consists of (1) two interlocking domestic rules requiring in-
come inclusion (for residence countries (IIR) and denial of deduction for
source countries (UTPR), together referred to as the Global anti-Base Ero-
sion (“GLoBE”) Rules, and (2) a treaty-based rule (STTR).
1. Domestic Rules: Global Anti-Base Erosion (“GloBE”) Rules
GloBE Rules, have two components: income inclusion (IIR) and denial
of deduction (UTPR). MNEs that meet the €750 million Euros revenue
threshold determined under BEPS Action 13 (country-by-country reporting)
are subject to a global minimum tax regardless of the jurisdiction where
153. Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, The New International Tax Framework: Evolution or Revo-
lution?, 25 A
M.SOCY INTL L. 11 (2021), http://www.asil.org/insights/volume/25/issue/11.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 531
they are headquartered or operating.
154
Also, the Statement makes it clear
that the U.S. GILTI regime will co-exist with the GloBE rules.
155
First, the IIR requires the residence countries of multinational corpora-
tions to impose top-up tax
156
on an ultimate parent entity (“UPE”) at a min-
imum rate of fifteen percent if the source country where a subsidiary oper-
ates imposes tax below such minimum rate on the subsidiary’s income. The
fifteen percent global minimum tax rate is an effective rate, not a nominal
rate.
157
The IIR allocates top-up tax based on a top-down approach subject
to a split-ownership rule for shareholdings below eighty percent.
158
With the
single tax principle in mind, this rule acts as a corrective measure that al-
lows residence countries to tax if source taxation is not substantial enough
to count once.”
Second, if a residence country does not impose this minimum tax, the
subsidiary’s deduction for payment to the parent entity would be denied or
an equivalent adjustment would be required as per the UTPR to the extent
that the low tax income of a subsidiary is not subject to tax under an IIR.
159
This represents an additional corrective measure to guarantee substantial
source taxation if residence countries do not cooperate.
To illustrate, suppose that a subsidiary in the source country earns $100
USD of income and the source country imposes tax at ten percent, which is
below the fifteen percent global minimum tax rate. Then, the residence
country of the parent entity includes the $100 USD in the parent’s income
and imposes tax at a rate that is equal to the difference between the fifteen
percent of global minimum rate and the said ten percent tax rate. Suppose
further that the subsidiary pays the $100 USD to the parent in a deductible
form, such as a royalty. If the residence country does not have the IIR, the
subsidiary’s deduction for the $100 USD royalty payment will be denied.
Pascal Saint-Amans, the director of the OECD’s Center for Tax Policy
and Administration, explains that the UTPR is intended as an insurance pol-
154. Statement, supra note 1, at 4 (explaining that government entities, international or-
ganizations, non-profit organizations, pension funds or investment funds that are Ultimate
Parent Entities (“UPE”) of an MNE Group or any holding vehicles used by such entities, or-
ganizations or funds are not subject to the Global Anti-Base Erosion (“GloBE”) rules).
155. Id. at 5.
156. A top-up tax allows the residence country to tax the difference between the appli-
cable tax rate in a particular country up to the agreed global minimum tax rate. David Lawder
& Leigh Thomas, Explainer: What is a Global Minimum Tax and How Could it Affect Com-
panies, Countries? R
EUTERS (Apr. 14, 2021, 8:50 AM), http://www.reuters.com/business
/what-is-global-minimum-tax-how-could-it-affect-companies-countries-2021-04-14. For ex-
ample, if a country only taxed at eleven percent, the residence country could tax the difference
of four percent to ensure the fifteen percent global minimum was achieved.
157. Statement, supra note 1, at 4 (explaining that this effective tax rate is calculated on
a jurisdictional basis and uses a common definition of covered taxes and tax a tax base deter-
mined by reference to financial accounting income).
158. Id.
159. Id at 3.
532 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
icy against countries that refuse to implement Pillar Two.
160
If companies
move to non-cooperating jurisdictions in hope of gaining a tax advantage,
the effect would be fully neutralized. However, certain MNEs will not be
subject to the undertaxed payment rule for the first five years after meeting
the €750 million Euros revenue threshold if their foreign tangible assets do
not exceed €50 million Euros and they operate in no more than five foreign
countries.
161
There are important carve-outs to the GloBE rules.
162
First, the sub-
stance-based carve-out of income from the Pillar Two rules will exempt, in
the first year, eight percent of the carrying value of tangible assets and ten
percent of payroll. These percentages will decline by 0.2 percent each year
for the next five years, and by 0.4 percent (for tangible assets) and 0.8 per-
cent (for payroll) each year for the subsequent five years, after which the
exemption will be five percent of both tangible assets and payroll. Second, a
de minimis carve-out will exclude profits from countries where the MNE
has less than €10 million Euros in revenue and less than €1 million Euros in
profits. The Statement offers that there will be further carve-outs, such as
safe harbors, in the implementation documents.
163
These substantial carve-
outs harm the spirit of the single tax principle, and infra Part IV.B.2 dis-
cusses their pitfalls.
2. Treaty-Based Rule: Subject to Tax Rule (“STTR”)
The STTR is a standalone treaty rule whose origin can be traced back to
Stanley Surrey’s U.S. tax treaty policy in the 1960s, discussed in Part II.A.1.
It specifically targets intercompany payments that exploit treaties to shift
profits to low-tax jurisdictions.
164
Therefore, this rule applies to certain cat-
egories of deductible payments that present a greater risk of base erosion,
such as interest and royalties.
165
There were negotiations by the Inclusive
Framework regarding the minimum rate for STTR, between 7.5 percent and
nine percent,
166
however, the Statement stipulates that the minimum rate
will be nine percent.
167
160. Alex Parker, How the Global Tax Agreement Could Backfire for Biden, LAW360
(Oct. 18, 2021), http://www.law360.com/tax-authority/articles/1431269/how-the-global-tax-
agreement-could-backfire-for-biden.
161. Statement, supra note 1, at 4.
162. In addition to the two carve-outs in the text above, international shipping income is
excluded from the GloBE rules. Statement, supra note 1, at 5.
163. Id. at 4–5.
164. OECD, T
AX CHALLENGES ARISING FROM DIGITALISATION - REPORT ON PILLAR
TWO BLUEPRINT: INCLUSIVE FRAMEWORK ON BEPS, OECD/G20 BASE EROSION AND
PROFIT SHIFTING PROJECT 150, ¶ 566 (2020), http://doi.org/10.1787/abb4c3d1-en [hereinaf-
ter, P
ILLAR TWO BLUEPRINT].
165. Id. at 150, ¶ 568.
166. OECD,
STATEMENT ON A TWO-PILLAR SOLUTION TO ADDRESS THE TAX
CHALLENGES ARISING FROM THE DIGITALISATION OF THE ECONOMY 5 (July 1, 2021),
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 533
For example, suppose that a subsidiary in the source country pays a
royalty to a parent company of $100 USD, and the parent’s $100 USD roy-
alty income is subject to a nominal tax rate of one percent below the mini-
mum rate (nine percent) in the residence country. Then, the source country
is allowed to impose withholding tax on the royalty payment at a rate that is
equal to the difference between the minimum rate provided for under the
STTR (nine percent) and the said nominal tax rate (one percent).
168
3. Model Rules
The Statement provides, “[p]illar Two should be brought into law in
2022, to be effective in 2023, with the UTPR coming into effect in 2024.”
169
The OECD/Inclusive Framework will present Model Rules for Pillar Two to
define the scope and mechanics of the GloBE rules and provide a template
for domestic legislation to implement the GloBE regime. The OECD
/Inclusive Framework will also provide model treaty provisions to give ef-
fect to the STTR by mid-2022.
170
At the end of 2022, the OECD expects to
have an implementation framework to facilitate the coordinated implemen-
tation of the GloBE rules.
171
In December 2021, the OCED/Inclusive Framework released Model
Rules for Pillar Two, consisting of ten chapters that explained the GloBE
regime in detail.
172
In addition to this seventy-page document, the OECD
/Inclusive Framework distributed Commentary to the Model Rules (Pillar
Two) later in March 2022, which is about 230 pages long. There are multi-
ple supplements issued by the OECD/Inclusive Framework,
173
but the au-
thors found the six-page fact sheets most helpful for many readers.
174
http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/statement-on-a-two-pillar-solution-to-address-the-tax-challenges-
arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-the-economy-july-2021.pdf [hereinafter J
ULY STATEMENT].
167.Statement, supra note 1, at 5.
168. P
ILLAR TWO BLUEPRINT, supra note 164, at 165, ¶ 650.
169.Statement, supra note 1, at 5.
170. G
LOBAL ANTI-BASE EROSION MODEL RULES (PILLAR TWO), FREQUENTLY ASKED
QUESTIONS, OECD 6 (Dec. 2021). The model treaty provisions were supposed to be released
in November 2021, but the released was delayed to mid-2022.
171.Id.
172. T
AX CHALLENGES ARISING FROM THE DIGITALISATION OF THE ECONOMY
G
LOBAL ANTI-BASE EROSION MODEL RULES (PILLAR TWO), OECD (Dec. 2021), http://
www.oecd.org/tax/beps/tax-challenges-arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-theeconomy-global-
anti-base-erosion-model-rules-pillar-two.htm [hereinafter, Model Rules]. Chapter 1 addresses
questions of the GloBE scope. Chapters 2–5 contain the key operative rules. Chapter 6 deals
with mergers and acquisitions. Chapter 7 provides special rules that apply to certain tax neu-
trality and existing distribution tax regimes. Chapter 8 deals with administration, Chapter 9
provides for rules on transition and Chapter 10 contains definitions. Id. at 7.
173. See e.g., T
HE PILLAR TWO RULES IN A NUTSHELL, OECD (Dec. 2021), http://
www.oecd.org/tax/beps/pillar-two-model-rules-in-a-nutshell.pdf; O
VERVIEW OF THE KEY
OPERATING PROVISIONS OF THE GLOBE RULES, OECD (Dec. 2021), http://www.oecd.org/tax
534 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
FIGURE 1. TOP-UP TAX EXPLAINED
175
First, the Model Rules explain what “top-up tax” means in Pillar Two.
As Figure 1 shows, top-up tax first assumes a minimum tax amount relating
to the MNE’s excess profit calculated at the minimum tax rate of fifteen
percent. If certain Covered Taxes (in Step 3 below) paid by constituent enti-
ties of the MNE do not reach the minimum tax amount, the GloBE Rules
will impose an additional tax to fill the deficient tax amount. So, the top-up
tax seems to describe the tax rules that pull the top of the tax liability
amount up to a certain minimum level.
To determine top-up tax liability for an MNE, the Model Rules offer
five steps:
176
Step 1: An MNE Group determines whether it is within the
scope of the GloBE rules. If so, it identifies the location of
each Constituent Entity within the MNE Group.
Step 2: The MNE Group determines income of each con-
stituent entity. This so-called GloBE Income of a constitu-
ent entity is the income used for preparing a consolidated
financial statement of the ultimate parent entity.
177
Step 3: The MNE Group determines taxes attributable to
income determined in Step 2. (Covered Taxes)
Step 4: The MNE Group calculates the effective tax rate of
all Constituent Entities located in the same jurisdiction. If
an MNE is subject to an effective tax rate below fifteen
percent in any jurisdiction, calculate the top-up tax with re-
spect to that low tax jurisdiction.
Step 5: The MNE Group is liable to the so-impose top-up
tax under IIR in the residence country or UTPR in the
source country in accordance with the agreed rule order.
178
/beps/pillar-two-GloBE-rules-fact-sheets.pdf (referred to as “fact sheets” in the file name as-
signed by the OECD).
174.Id.
175.Id. at 1.
176.Id.
177.Model Rules, supra note 172, at 15, art. 3.1.
178. Jinyan Li makes a noteworthy observation on the Model Rules’ revised approach
on the UTPR. See Li, supra note 31 (explaining that the UTPR is similar to the U.S. BEAT
rule as an anti-base-erosion rule with respect to MNEs’ intragroup payments. But the Model
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 535
The initial and overwhelming responses from MNEs are that the Model
Rules are so complex that they need to be simplified.
179
For example, Step 4
requires MNEs to calculate their effective tax rate in each jurisdiction where
they do business. It is a novel compliance challenge that requires MNEs to
prepare new information systems.
180
The OECD/Inclusive Framework also
acknowledges the challenges, so the OECD/Inclusive Framework promises
to develop safe harbors that let MNEs avoid full calculations of top-up tax
in certain circumstances.
181
However, the Model Rules Commentary did not
include the details on safe harbors, so MNEs have to wait until, hopefully,
later in 2022 for this issue to be resolved.
B. The U.S. Implementation of Pillar Two through the
Build Back Better (“BBB”) Act
The recently unveiled international tax provisions of the BBB Act
182
represent the United States’ plan to implement Pillar Two. They also serve
as a significant move toward the United States’ implementation of the single
tax principle by introducing various mechanisms to ensure that cross-border
income is taxed once at a substantive tax rate. This Subpart discusses the
proposed changes in the BBB and how they fit in with the new international
tax regime, especially Pillar Two.
1. Global Intangible Low Tax Income (“GILTI”)
Probably the most important element in the BBB Act is the modifica-
tion of the GILTI rules. The BBB Act raises the GILTI tax rate from 10.5
Rule removes the link to intragroup payments and makes the UTPR a modified formulary ap-
portionment to share tax base among countries. Li concludes that such modified approach de-
parts from the international consensus on the original version of Pillar Two UTPR and may be
incompatible with tax treaties.).
179. See e.g., Isabel Gottlieb, Companies Eager to See Details on Minimum Tax Simpli-
fications,B
LOOMBERG TAX (Mar. 23, 2022), http://news.bloombergtax.com/daily-tax-report-
international/companies-eager-to-see-details-on-minimum-tax-simplifications; Allison Chris-
tians, Full Professor, H. Heward Stikeman Chair in Tax Law, McGill University Faculty of
Law, Oral Presentation “Let the GILTI GloBE Games Begin” at the 4th Annual UCI Law–A.
Lavar Taylor Tax Symposium (Mar. 21, 2022); BEPS Monitoring Group Comments on the
Model Rules for a Global Anti-Base-Erosion Minimum Corporate Tax, supra note 28, at
1427.
180. Gottlieb, supra note 179.
181.Model Rules, supra note 172, at 47, art. 8.2. However, BEPS Monitoring Group
criticizes that such safe harbors protect the interest of MNEs and may harm the goal of Pillar
Two. BEPS Monitoring Group Comments on the Model Rules for a Global Anti-Base-Erosion
Minimum Corporate Tax, supra note 28, at 1427.
182. H.R. 5376, 117th Cong. (2021) (Introduced in the House on Sept. 27, 2021, re-
ferred to the House Budget Committee, Build Back Better Act Rules Committee Print, updat-
ed Nov. 3, 2021) [hereinafter Build Back Better (“BBB”) Act].
536 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
percent
183
to fifteen percent
184
(15.8 percent with foreign tax credits), re-
duces the exemption ratio of tangible assets (QBAI) from ten percent
185
to
five percent,
186
and applies the GILTI rule on a country-by-country basis.
187
GILTI has been the most successful unilateral implementation of the
single tax principle by a residence country. But the proposed changes in the
BBB Act are intended to implement Pillar Two’s GloBE rules with other
participating countries. The new GILTI rate of fifteen percent is the same as
the global minimum tax rate of fifteen percent in Pillar Two. The reduction
of the QBAI limit to five percent is similar to the substance carve-out per-
mitted by the OECD.
188
Specifically, the OECD’s substance carve-out un-
der Pillar Two “will exclude an amount of income that is five percent of the
carrying value of tangible assets and payroll.
189
Country-by-country appli-
cation of GILTI is required by Pillar Two.
190
These changes in the U.S. law, if enacted, make it much more promis-
ing that the other G20 countries will enact similar changes. If all the G20
members follow up on their commitments to the Statement, the world will
be much closer to achieving the single tax principle. Since ninety percent of
large MNEs are headquartered in the G20,
191
this means that they will be
subject to the fifteen percent minimum tax in residence countries. That in
turn should enable source countries to apply the UTPR and the STTR with-
out worrying that an MNE can move its operations elsewhere to pay a lower
rate. As the single tax principle proposes, substantive taxation will exist in
either residence or source countries via corrective measures.
It is also important that the GILTI foreign tax credit limit is raised from
eighty percent to ninety-five percent,
192
because that means that source
183. Daniel Bunn, Piling on the GILTI Verdicts,TAX FOUND. (July 15, 2021),
http://taxfoundation.org/biden-gilti-proposal/ (“Half of GILTI is taxed at the U.S. corporate
rate of 21 percent, which means the basic rate on GILTI is 10.5 percent.”).
184. BBB Act, H.R. 5347, § 138131(a)(3) (2021).
185. I.R.C. § 951A(b)(2)(A).
186. BBB Act, H.R. 5347, § 138126(d) (2021).
187. BBB Act, H.R. 5347, § 138124(a) (2021). GILTI is currently calculated using
MNEs’ global average tax rates, but under BBB, GILTI would be calculated based on a
MNEs operations in each individual country. Daniel Bunn, GILTI by Country is not as Simple
as it Seems, T
AX FOUND. (May 18, 2021), http://taxfoundation.org/gilti-by-country/. For game
theoretic model analysis comparing a global average regime and a country-by-country regime,
see Sanchirico, supra note 31 (suggesting that a global average model is superior to a country-
by-country regime).
188.Statement, supra note 1, at 4.
189.Id.
190.Statement, supra note 1, at 5 (“It is agreed that Pillar Two will apply a minimum
rate on a jurisdictional basis. In that context, consideration will be given to the conditions un-
der which the US GILTI regime will co-exist with the GloBE rules, to ensure a level playing
field.”).
191. Saez & Zucman, supra note 67.
192. BBB Act, H.R. 5347, § 138127(a) (2021).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 537
country taxes that meet the global minimum tax rate will be almost fully
creditable against residence taxation. This change shows another important
element of the single tax principle, because if a source tax is substantial
enough to satisfy the global minimum tax rate, it counts as taxing “once”
and thus residence taxation yields to source to guarantee a “single” tax on
such income. Then why not allow 100 percent of foreign tax credit instead
of limiting it to ninety-five percent? The limitation presumably intends to
remind U.S. MNEs to consider U.S. tax implications instead of simply pay-
ing foreign taxes without consideration at the expense of the U.S. tax reve-
nue.
We would have preferred the global minimum tax rate in Pillar Two
and the GILTI rate proposed by the Biden administration to be higher than
fifteen percent—for example, twenty-one percent—because twenty-one
percent is the current corporate income tax rate of the United States
193
and
is closer to the average corporate tax rate of the G20 (26.96 percent).
194
Fur-
thermore, we would have preferred to eliminate the QBAI exemption for
offshore tangible assets because there is no reason to limit the corrective
measures initiated by the residence country, such as GILTI, to income from
offshore intangible assets. Nonetheless, the GILTI provisions in the BBB
Act represent a reasonable compromise position to realize the single tax
principle.
Some Democrats in the U.S. House of Representatives, such as Con-
gressmen Tom O’Halleran, Henry Cuellar, and Lou Correa, expressed con-
cern that the changes to GILTI in the BBB Act could reduce the competi-
tiveness of U.S. MNEs.
195
Their concern is primarily that the U.S.
government has moved too quickly by instituting these rules before the rest
of the world and creating what they argue are new rules, specifically, the
country-by-country regime.
196
These Congressmen posit that the “new rules
in the [Ways and Means Committee’s] draft would allow other countries to
take advantage of our rules, and harm U.S. companies. If we wait, it will al-
low Congress the opportunity to adjust the implementation of the policy
based on how G20 countries write their own GILTI regimes.”
197
193. I.R.C. § 11.
194. Asen, supra note 28.
195. Lawmakers Recommend Caution on GILTI Changes,T
AX NOTES (Oct. 8, 2021),
http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-today-international/global-intangible-low-taxed-income-
gilti/lawmakers-recommend-caution-gilti-changes/2021/10/20/7bcn7?highlight=headquartered%
20G20.
196.Id.
197.Id.
538 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
2. Foreign Tax Credit (“FTC”) Limitations
The BBB Act requires FTC determinations on a country-by-country ba-
sis.
198
This tightens up the availability of the FTC by adding another cap to
the creditable amount of foreign taxes per country. The new per-country
limitation on top of the existing basket limitations (per category of income)
in the FTC rules
199
finally achieves the Reagan Administration’s proposal
from 1985,
200
which suggested both per category and per country limits ap-
plicable to FTCs.
Since the TCJA reduced the corporate tax rate to twenty-one percent,
most U.S. MNEs paying taxes to foreign countries would be in an excess
FTC position, meaning that the MNEs’ foreign taxes exceed the credit limit
allowed by the U.S. tax law.
201
Furthermore, the proposed global minimum
tax rate of fifteen percent is still lower than the U.S. corporate tax rate of
twenty-one percent, which may still offer room for moderate tax competi-
tion among countries. Hence, allowing generous FTCs to U.S. MNEs would
reduce U.S. tax revenue, undermining its social safety net. In that regard,
the BBB Act’s tightened FTC rule is essential to prevent cross-crediting
202
(as allowed by the TCJA) and to curb an incentive to invest in lower tax
foreign jurisdictions. Furthermore, this change would also reduce the incen-
tives of source countries to engage in tax competition by granting a tax hol-
iday, because even if they offer a low tax rate to U.S. MNEs, that would on-
ly decrease the MNEs’ overall FTC availability due to the BBB Act’s per-
country limitation.
203
198. BBB Act, H.R. 5347, § 138124(a) (2021).
199.Cf.Michael Smith, Complexity of Biden’s FTC Proposals Sparks Worry,T
AX NOTES
(Nov. 15, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-federal/corporate-taxation/complexity-
bidens-ftc-proposals-sparks-worry/2021/11/15/7cl9w?highlight=build%20back%20better
(commenting that the new rule will add complication and thus administrability concerns:
“While the rules may look like those historically used when analyzing FTCs, the differences
between the Biden proposal and the per-country system of 1932 and 1960 are massive”).
200. W
HITE HOUSE,THE PRESIDENTS TAX PROPOSALS TO THE CONGRESS FOR
FAIRNESS,GROWTH, AND SIMPLICITY (May 1985), 389–96.
201. Garrett Watson, Tax Reform’s Broader Corporate Tax Base Opens More to Biden’s
Proposed Rate Hike,T
AX FOUND. (June 22, 2021), http://taxfoundation.org/us-corporate-tax-
base/ (“The TCJA reduced the corporate tax rate from 35 percent to 21 percent beginning in
2018. . .”).
202. C
ONG.RSCH.SERV., R45186, ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE TAXATION:
T
HE 2017 REVISION (P.L. 115-97) 3 (2021), http://sgp.fas.org/crs/misc/R45186.pdf (“Cross-
crediting occurs when credits for taxes paid to one country that are in excess of the U.S. tax
due on income from that country can be used to offset U.S. tax due on income earned in a
second country that imposes little or no tax.”).
203. The foregone cross-crediting eliminated by the BBB Act might have a synergy with
the anti-deferral rules in the TCJA.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 539
3. Foreign-Derived Intangible Income (“FDII”)
The Foreign-Derived Intangible Income (“FDII”) rule provides that
owners of intellectual property held in the United States with sales to for-
eign customers are subject to a lower tax rate than the regular corporate tax
rate of twenty-one percent.
204
Currently the effective tax rate is 13.125 per-
cent.
205
FDII has given an important advantage to U.S. MNEs with valuable
intangible property and significant exports, such as Apple and Google.
The BBB Act only raises the FDII effective tax rate from 13.125 per-
cent to 15.8 percent.
206
The effective tax rate increases because the BBB
Act reduces the deduction under Section 250 of the Internal Revenue Code
for FDII to 21.875 percent.
207
The proposed effective tax rate is still lower
than the regular corporate tax rate of twenty-one percent. However, recently
there has been some evidence that the FDII rule does induce intangible
property migration to the United States.
208
So, on balance, the revised rule
in the BBB Act shows improvement.
Nonetheless, the fundamental problem with FDII, besides its complexi-
ty, persists: Allowing a lower tax rate for U.S. MNEs with intangibles asso-
ciated with export is a blatant violation of the World Trade Organization
subsidies code.
209
The fact that FDII may be working increases the incentive
204. Daniel Bunn, Will FDII Stay or Will It Go?,TAX FOUND. (Aug. 10, 2021),
http://taxfoundation.org/will-fdii-stay-will-go/ (“Like a patent box, FDII was meant to en-
courage companies to keep their intellectual property (IP) in the U.S. or bring it back to the
U.S. from offshore locations.”).
205. I.R.C. § 250(a). The Foreign-Derived Intangible Income (“FDII”) deduction reduc-
es the effective tax rate from twenty-one percent to 13.125%. Frank J. Vari, Foreign-derived
Intangible Income Deduction: Tax Reform’s Overlooked New Benefit for U.S. Corporate Ex-
porters,T
AX ADVISER (Aug. 2, 2018), http://www.thetaxadviser.com/newsletters/2018/aug
/foreign-derived-intangible-income-deduction.html.
206. Alex Durante, Cody Kallen, Huaqun Li, William McBride, Alex Muresianu, Erica
York & Garret Watson, Build Back Better Act: Details & Analysis of Tax Provisions in the
$1.75 Trillion Reconciliation Bill,T
AX FOUND. (Nov. 5, 2021), http://taxfoundation.org/build-
back-better-plan-reconciliation-bill-tax (“[BBB] reduce[s] the deduction for Foreign-Derived
Intangible Income (FDII) to 21.875 percent, resulting in a tax rate of 15.8 percent, effective
for tax years beginning after December 31, 2022.”).
207.Id.
208. Martin A. Sullivan, Big Tech Is Moving Profit to the United States,T
AX NOTES
(Aug. 23, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-federal/corporate-taxation/big-tech-moving-
profit-united-states/2021/08/23/776cs; Daniel Bunn, Intellectual Property Came Back to U.S.
After Tax Reform, But Proposals Could Change That,T
AX FOUND. (July 21, 2021), http://
taxfoundation.org/intellectual-property-tax-proposals.
209. Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures,
Marrakesh Agreement on
Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 1A, 1869 U.N.T.S. 14; see also I
NTL
TRADE ADMIN., TRADE GUIDE:WTOSUBSIDIES AGREEMENT, http://www.trade.gov/trade-
guide-wto-subsidies (last visited Mar. 2, 2022) (“A subsidy granted by a WTO member gov-
ernment is prohibited by the Subsidies Agreement if it is contingent, in law or in fact, on ex-
port performance, or on the use of domestic over imported goods. These prohibited subsidies
are commonly referred to as export subsidies and import substitution subsidies, respectively.
540 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
for foreign trading partners to sue the United States in the World Trade Or-
ganization.
4. Base Erosion and Anti-Abuse Tax (“BEAT”)
The TCJA introduced the Base Erosion and Anti-Abuse Tax (“BEAT”)
to prevent base erosion and profit shifting.
210
It denies deductions for certain
otherwise deductible payments from a U.S. corporation to a related foreign
corporation and instead imposes a tax at ten percent (12.5 percent starting in
2026) payable to the United States.
211
This rule is intended to protect suffi-
cient taxation in source countries.
However, the BEAT has not been very successful so far in raising the
revenue that policymakers expected in 2017 when they introduced it.
212
But
there is evidence that BEAT revenue may be increasing and that this is like-
ly to continue, as the BBB Act increases the BEAT rate applicable to the
base erosion payments from ten percent in 2022 (12.5 percent in 2023, fif-
teen percent in 2024) to eighteen percent starting in 2025.
213
The BBB Act
also fixes some important problems with the BEAT by applying the BEAT
to, for example, interest expenses capitalized into inventory.
214
The most
important change is making the BEAT application by source countries con-
ditional on the tax rate of residence countries, which is consistent with the
single tax principle and the UTPR of Pillar Two.
215
5. Alternative Minimum Tax (“AMT”) for Corporations
A domestic tax provision in the BBB Act that is also relevant to the sin-
gle tax principle in the new international tax regime is the new book-
based
216
alternative minimum tax (“AMT”) for corporations, set at fifteen
They are deemed to be specific and are viewed as particularly harmful under the Subsidies
Agreement and U.S. law.”).
210. I
NTERNAL REVENUE SERV., IRS PROVIDES ADDITIONAL GUIDANCE ON BASE
EROSION AND ANTI-ABUSE TAX, (2020), http://www.irs.gov/newsroom/irs-provides-additional-
guidance-on-base-erosion-and-anti-abuse-tax.
211. I.R.C. §§ 59A(b)(1)(A), 59A(b)(2)(A).
212. Martin A. Sullivan, Economic Analysis: The BEAT Is Down but Not out,T
AX
NOTES (Aug. 9, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-today-international/base-erosion-
and-antiabuse-tax-beat/economic-analysis-beat-down-not-out/2021/08/09/76zw8; see also U.S.
D
EPT TREASURY,THE MADE IN AMERICA TAX PLAN 12 (2021), http://home.treasury.gov
/system/files/136/MadeInAmericaTaxPlan_Report.pdf.
213. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138131(a)(3) (2021) (indicating that the BEAT rate will be
ten percent in 2022, 12.5 percent in 2023, fifteen percent in 2024, and eighteen percent in
2025 and thereafter); see also Sullivan, supra note 212.
214. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138131(b)(2).
215. See infra Part III.A.1.
216. Referring to the amount of income corporations publicly report to shareholders in
financial statements. Durante, et al., supra note 206.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 541
percent.
217
The AMT was designed to reduce a taxpayer’s ability to avoid
taxes by using certain deductions and other tax benefit items.
218
The TCJA
repealed the AMT for corporations, but the BBB Act reintroduces it.
219
The
new rule applies to MNEs with an average revenue of over $1 billion
USD.
220
The modified corporate AMT rule applies to both U.S. MNEs and
foreign MNEs whose U.S. revenue exceeds $100 million USD over three
years.
221
Thus, it is an important backstop to the BEAT as well as GILTI by
offering another minimum tax rate. It is also consistent with both the IIR for
residence country and the UTPR for source country.
222
6. A New Cap on Interest Expense Deduction
For domestic subsidiaries of foreign MNEs, the BBB Act contains a
new cap on net interest expense deduction. The provision limits deductions
of net interest expenses to 110 percent of the ratio of the domestic subsidi-
ary’s Earnings Before Interest, Tax, Depreciation and Amortization
(“EBITDA”) to the MNE’s EBITDA.
223
This is another protection in addi-
tion to the BEAT to prevent the base-erosion payments by MNEs.
7. Room for Improvement
Overall, the international tax provisions in the BBB Act show commit-
ment by the United States to the implementation of Pillar Two and a global
minimum tax. They also mark a substantial improvement over the TCJA’s
international tax provisions, as shown in the increased GILTI and BEAT
rates and the tightened FTC rules. They are likely to produce significant
revenue and therefore help strengthen the U.S. social safety net.
However, like any legislation that needs to receive a majority vote in
Congress, the provisions of the BBB Act represent a compromise. To better
realize the single tax principle and combat tax competition, the BBB Act
could have proposed a higher GILTI rate with more rigorous anti-base ero-
sion rules.
Furthermore, the BBB Act still lacks an anti-inversion rule. Corporate
inversion, also known as tax inversion, occurs when a domestic company
moves its headquarters or base of operations overseas to reduce its tax bur-
dens.
224
Inversion occurs when MNEs shop around countries looking for
217. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138101(a).
218. I
NTERNAL REVENUE SERV., TOPIC NO.556ALTERNATIVE MINIMUM TAX (last up-
dated Jan. 21, 2022), http://www.irs.gov/taxtopics/tc556.
219. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138101.
220. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138101(a)(2), at 1733.
221. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138101(a)(2), at 1733.
222. See infra Part III.A.1.
223. BBB Act, H.R. 5376, § 138111(a).
224. See Omri Marian, Home-Country Effects of Corporate Inversions, 90 W
ASH.L.
R
EV. 1 (2015); Cathy Hwang, The New Corporate Migration: Tax Diversion Through Inver-
sion, 80 B
ROOK.L.REV. 807 (2015).
542 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
low(er) tax rates, resulting in tax competition among countries hoping to
host migrating MNEs. Before the TCJA, when the maximum corporate tax
rate was thirty-five percent, a lot of U.S. pharmaceutical companies with
valuable intangible assets inverted, and low-tax Ireland was a popular new
corporate home.
225
In 2004, Congress added Section 7874 to the Internal
Revenue Code, which significantly limits the tax benefits associated with
corporate inversions.
226
However, more than twenty high-profile inversions
were still reported in the early 2010s.
227
The number has reduced signifi-
cantly since the TCJA reduced the corporate tax rate to twenty-one percent,
and the BBB Act maintains the corporate tax rate as twenty-one percent.
228
But twenty-one percent is still higher than the global minimum tax rate of
fifteen percent, and U.S. MNEs may still want to relocate to other countries
with the minimum tax rate of fifteen percent. A corporate inversion that
manages to avoid Section 7874 will not be subject to GILTI or the anti-
inversion provisions of the BEAT, because that corporation will no longer
be a U.S. taxpayer. Such an inversion may keep tax competition going
among countries until the global effective tax rate hits fifteen percent. Given
that Pillar Two does not guarantee the full harmony of global corporate tax
rates, the BBB Act should have included a more robust anti-inversion
rule.
229
8. Compatibility with Pillar Two Model Rules
The proposed BBB Act was passed by the House of Representatives in
November 2021, but not by the Senate.
230
If the BBB Act is enacted in the
version that passed the House, the United States will be fully compliant with
Pillar Two Model Rules, because both the GILTI rate and the BEAT rate
would be raised to fifteen percent, and the BEAT rate would be made con-
tingent upon low taxation at residence, so that the BEAT operates as a
UTPR.
225. Zachary Midler, Quick Take: Tax Inversion,BLOOMBERG (Mar. 2, 2017, 4:35 PM),
http://www.bloomberg.com/quicktake/tax-inversion.
226. See I.R.C. § 7874(a)(1).
227. Midler, supra note 225.
228. Garrett Watson, Tax Base Opens More to Biden’s Proposed Rate Hike,T
AX
FOUND. (June 22, 2021) http://taxfoundation.org/us-corporate-tax-base (indicating the TCJA
reduced the corporate income tax rate from thirty-five to twenty-one percent).
229. For example, policymakers may consider reducing the threshold in Section 7874 to,
for example, fifty percent and including a managed and controlled alternative definition of
corporate residency.
230. Christina Wilkie, House Passes $1.75 Trillion Biden Plan That Funds Universal
Pre-K, Medicare Expansion and Renewable Energy Credits, CNBC (Nov. 19, 2021),
http://www.cnbc.com/2021/11/19/biden-build-back-better-bill-house-passes-social-safety-net-
and-climate-plan.html; Yacob Reyes, Tim Kaine: Build Back Better Is ‘Dead But Core Provi-
sions Will Pass,A
XIOS (Jan. 16, 2022), http://www.axios.com/tim-kaine-spending-package-
6560dd77-b5bc-4d86-893e-dabfebc7e57a.html.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 543
First, raising the GILTI rate to fifteen percent is consistent with the IIR,
for which the Pillar Two Model Rules require a top-up tax to fifteen percent
imposed at the parent level of a multinational. The QBAI exception to
GILTI is consistent with Pillar Two’s substance carve-out from IIR.
231
In
this context, the OECD stated in a recent document that—
As noted in the Preamble to the Pillar Two Model Rules, considera-
tion will be given to the conditions under which the US Global In-
tangible Low-Taxed Income (GILTI) regime will co-exist with the
GloBE rules, to ensure a level playing field.
232
This assurance suggests that the Biden Administration has obtained a con-
cession that the GILTI will be considered as satisfying the IIR as long as the
rate is raised to at least fifteen percent.
Second, making BEAT contingent on the level of taxation in the resi-
dence country will ensure that BEAT operates in practice in a way that is
compatible with the UTPR.
233
In addition, the fact that UTPR comes after
IIR makes it less crucial whether the U.S. BEAT rule will firmly comply
with Pillar Two, because most foreign MNEs that are potentially subject to
the BEAT rule in the United States will be subject to IIR in their residence
countries first.
234
If the BBB Act is not enacted, however, then it is less likely that GILTI
and BEAT as enacted by the TCJA will be considered compatible with Pil-
lar Two. First, the current GILTI rate of 10.5 percent is well below the IIR
minimum tax rate of fifteen percent in the residence country. As a result,
U.S. MNEs will in many cases be subject to UTPR in the source country.
Unfortunately, it is not certain whether those corrective taxes imposed by
the source country under UTPR would be creditable against the U.S. MNEs
U.S. tax liabilities. Some commentators seem to believe that the source
taxation under UTPR is creditable, resulting in significant shifting of tax
revenue from the United States to foreign jurisdictions.
235
However, it is al-
so possible that the source taxation under UTPR is not creditable. The Unit-
ed States has recently amended its foreign tax credit rules to make it more
difficult to get a credit for foreign taxes in the absence of what the United
231. I.R.C. § 951A(b)(2)(A). Even though the BBB Act calculates the QBAI exception a
bit differently (based on assets rather than assets and payroll), it would be considered a minor
variation.
232. OECD, T
HE PILLAR TWO RULES IN A NUTSHELL 2 (Dec. 2021), http://
www.oecd.org/tax/beps/pillar-two-model-rules-in-a-nutshell.pdf.
233. BEAT was introduced as an alternative minimum tax in the TCJA and not a top-up
tax mechanism as envisioned by Pillar Two. However, the BBB Act’s revision of BEAT rule
may make it compliant to UTPR.
234. The BEAT has a $500 million USD revenue threshold. I.R.C. § 59A(e)(1)(B).
235. Dylan Moroses, US Could Lose Tax Revenue If It Neglects OECD’s Pillar 2,
L
AW360 TAX AUTHORITY (Mar. 18, 2022), http://www.law360.com/tax-authority/articles
/1475431/us-could-lose-tax-revenue-if-it-neglects-oecd-s-pillar-2.
544 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
States considers adequate nexus to a foreign country.
236
This change was
designed to clarify that DSTs are not creditable.
237
But the scope of the new
foreign tax credit rule is broad and may apply to the source taxation under
UTPR to deny foreign tax credits, causing double taxation in the residence
(U.S.) and source countries.
Second, the current BEAT rate of ten percent is likewise too low for
UTPR purposes in the source country. In addition, the current BEAT is not
contingent on the level of the residence country taxation. As a result, it is
likely that BEAT will not be compliant with Pillar Two, and thus, foreign
residence countries will not respect the U.S. tax paid under BEAT rules
when they apply IIR, causing double taxation in the residence and source
countries.
238
Therefore, the tax consequences of not complying with Pillar Two
when the rest of the world does comply are likely to be tax revenue loss in
the United States and the increased risk of double taxation by taxpayers.
The results harm the single tax principle that the global deal aims to accom-
plish. Hence, the authors of this article hope that Congress will pass the
provisions relating to Pillar Two in 2022 as is proposed in the BBB Act, re-
gardless of how they are rebranded and repromoted.
In March 2022, the U.S. Department of the Treasury released the
Greenbook for fiscal year 2023.
239
This publication outlines and explains
the Biden Administration’s tax proposals. The budget released by Treasury
assumes that the BBB Act, as passed by the House of Representatives on
November 19, 2021, will be enacted.
240
However, if the corporate tax rate
would increase to twenty-eight percent, the GILTI rate would automatically
increase to twenty-one percent.
IV. PROMISES AND PITFALLS OF THE GLOBAL MINIMUM TAX
Pillar Two would significantly reduce MNEs’ incentives to change their
place of residence or the location of their headquarters to exploit tax compe-
236. 87 Fed. Reg. 276 (Jan. 4, 2022) (Guidance Related to the Foreign Tax Credit; Clari-
fication of Foreign-Derived Intangible Income).
237.Id. at 289–90.
238. Current BEAT may not only be incompatible with Pillar Two, but also has another
problem. Some commentators argue that BEAT is discriminatory because it applies only to
payments to related foreign parties by partially denying deductions, and thus may violate Art.
24 (nondiscrimination) of most tax treaties. See H. David Rosenbloom and Fadi Shaheen, The
BEAT and the Treaties, 92 T
AX NOTES INTL 53 (2018); Reuven S. Avi-Yonah and Brett
Wells, The Beat and Treaty Overrides: A Brief Response to Rosenbloom and Shaheen, 6
(U
NIV.MICH.LAW &ECON. Working Papers, 2018).
239. U.S.
D
EPT TREASURY,GENERAL EXPLANATIONS OF THE ADMINISTRATIONS
FISCAL YEAR 2023 REVENUE PROPOSALS (2022).
240.Id.at iii (stating that the revenue proposals based on provisions of Title XIII of
H.R. 5376 as passed by the House of Representatives on November 19, 2021, except for Sec.
137601).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 545
tition by source countries. However, it is important to note that Pillar Two
also offers measures for effective residence-based taxation. This Part dis-
cusses the promises and pitfalls of Pillar Two. First, we discuss the promise
of global tax reform, specifically, raising additional revenue and reducing
profit shifting. Second, we explore the various challenges facing Pillar Two,
notably, concerns of developing countries, various carve-outs, and the logis-
tical puzzle of implementation.
A. Promise of the New International Tax Regime
Many policymakers who participated in the global tax deal hail the
Statement as a long-waited international tax reform and an important step in
combatting tax competition, tax base erosion, and profit shifting. Mathias
Cormann, OECD Secretary-General said that “the deal would make the in-
ternational corporate tax system ‘fairer and work better.’”
241
We believe
that Pillar Two, in particular, would generate substantial revenue and lead to
behavioral changes in both countries and taxpayers to engage in less tax
competition. In short, Pillar Two is the modern embodiment of the single
tax principle.
1. Additional Revenue
Pillar Two, with its global minimum corporate income tax of fifteen
percent, is expected to generate approximately $150 billion USD in addi-
tional global tax revenues each year.
242
While the primary revenue effects of
Pillar One will be the reallocation of profits (about $100 billion USD) to
source countries annually,
243
Pillar Two is a true revenue generator. Hence,
from a global perspective, the global tax reform will benefit the world via
revenue generation.
244
The International Monetary Fund (“IMF”), represent-
ing an additional fifty-one countries, also backs the plan, indicating broader
global support outside the Inclusive Framework.
245
The additional revenue
241. Chris Giles, Emma Agyemang & Aime Williams, 136 Nations Agree to Biggest
Corporate Tax Deal in a Century,F
IN.TIMES (Oct. 8, 2021), http://www.ft.com/content
/5dc4e2d5-d7bd-4000-bf94-088f17e21936.
242. OECD,
T
WO-PILLAR SOLUTION TO ADDRESS THE TAX CHALLENGES ARISING
FROM THE
DIGITILISATION OF THE ECONOMY 5 (Oct. 2021), http://www.oecd.org/tax/beps
/brochure-two-pillar-solution-to-address-the-tax-challenges-arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-
the-economy-october-2021.pdf.
243. 130 Countries and Jurisdictions Join Bold New Framework for International Tax
Reform, OECD (July 1, 2021), http://www.oecd.org/newsroom/130-countries-and-jurisdictions-
join-bold-new-framework-for-international-tax-reform.htm.
244. William Horobin, Global Tax Overhaul Endorsed by 130 Nations as Deal Gets
Closer,B
LOOMBERG (July 1, 2021, 9:57 AM), http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles
/2021-07-01/global-tax-overhaul-endorsed-by-130-nations-as-deal-gets-closer.
245. Eric Martin, IMF Sees Room to Simplify Global Tax Deal to Boost Participation,
B
LOOMBERG (July 10, 2021), http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2021-07-10/imf-sees-
room-to-simplify-global-tax-deal-to-boost-participation.
546 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
generated by Pillar Two may be used to recover national economies from
the pandemic or to support sustainable tax policies relating to Environmen-
tal, Social, and Corporate Governance (“ESG”).
246
2. Reducing Profit Shifting and Tax Competition:
A Realization of the Single Tax Principle
Pillar Two mandates a fifteen percent global minimum tax, compelling
the global community to stop tax competition and the race to the bottom. As
a result, Pillar Two is expected to reduce profit shifting by MNEs. If enough
large economies agree to implement Pillar Two, there will be no incentive
for companies to move their businesses to low-tax jurisdictions. U.S. Treas-
ury Secretary Janet L. Yellen, who negotiated the deal, praised Pillar Two
as ending the race to the bottom on corporate taxation rates.
247
Therefore, Pillar Two resolves the traditional economics debate be-
tween advocates of capital export neutrality (“CEN”) and supporters of
capital import/ownership neutrality (“CIN”/ “CON”),
248
because this debate
rests on the assumption that corporate tax rates cannot be harmonized and
thus companies have different incentives for choice of location under each
theory.
249
However, if corporate tax rates are harmonized, as expected in
Pillar Two, then CEN, CIN, and CON can be achieved simultaneously.
250
Importantly, Pillar Two eliminates the main critique that has bedeviled
the United States’ attempts to raise taxes on its MNEs since the 1960s. The
argument that the unilateral adoption of higher rates of corporate tax on
MNEs’ foreign source income puts U.S. MNEs at a competitive disad-
246. Stephen Cooper, House Sends Biden’s $1.75T Budget Plan to Senate, LAW360
(Nov. 19, 2021), http://www.law360.com/tax-authority/federal/articles/1442179 (explaining
how the BBB Act plans to use revenue to pay for new or expanded tax incentives for child
care, renewable energy, and health care).
247. David J. Lynch, Global Minimum Tax Effort Moves Forward as Ireland and Hun-
gary Join Pact, W
ASH. POST (Oct. 8, 2021), http://www.washingtonpost.com/us-policy/2021
/10/08/minimum-corporate-tax-oecd-biden.
248. Capital export neutrality (“CEN”) refers to an investor’s choice between investing
her savings in her country of residence or in a foreign source country. CEN exists when resi-
dence and source country investments that earn the same pretax return also yield the same
after-tax return. On the other hand, capital import neutrality (“CIN”) requires that the earnings
from capital in a source country be taxed at the same rate for both domestic and foreign inves-
tors. Capital ownership neutrality (“CON”) is an alternative neutrality, demanding that taxa-
tion not influence who owns assets. See Mihir A. Desai & James R. Hines Jr., Evaluating In-
ternational Tax Reform, 56 N
ATL TAX J. 487 (2003); Michael J. Graetz, David R. Tillinghast
Lecture Taxing International Income: Inadequate Principles, Outdated Concepts, and Unsat-
isfactory Policies, 54 T
AX L. REV. 261, 270–77 (2001); Daniel Shaviro, The David R. Tilling-
hast Lecture - The Rising Tax-Electivity of U.S. Corporate Residence, 64 T
AX L. REV. 377,
386–87 (2010).
249. Desai & Hines, supra note 248; Graetz, supra note 248; Shaviro supra note 248.
250. Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Is It Time to Coordinate Corporate Tax Rates? A Note on
Horst (U. of Mich. Pub. L. & Legal Theory Rsch. Series, Paper No. 382, 2014), http://
ssrn.com/abstract=2389959 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2389959.
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 547
vantage vis-a-vis MNEs from other countries is often used.
251
This argu-
ment has never been persuasive because, both in the 1960s and today, U.S.
MNEs dominate their competition.
252
But it had political appeal, leading to
the TCJA reducing the corporate tax rate to twenty-one percent.
253
Howev-
er, such competitive rhetoric would disappear as a concern if all the G20
MNEs, which comprise over ninety percent of all MNEs, were subject to the
same minimum tax rate.
An important aspect of Pillar Two that is not addressed in the Statement
but is essential for successful implementation is the prevention of MNEs
from leaving the G20 and thereby escaping the IIR of residence country
(although perhaps not the UTPR/STTR). In most EU countries this is un-
likely because of their corporate exit taxes.
254
But the United States and the
United Kingdom do not have such taxes, making corporate exodus a viable
concern.
255
Furthermore, the United States has a different definition of cor-
porate residency from the rest of the world: A business incorporated in the
United States is a U.S. tax resident regardless of its domiciliary or place of
management,
256
whereas other countries, to a broad extent, use both the
place of incorporation and place of management tests.
257
Such mismatches
of corporate residence rules may aggravate the concern that, even if Pillar
Two firmly established the single tax principle in the G20, another form of
tax competition among non-G20 countries may emerge for hosting migrat-
ing companies.
B. Potential Challenges
So far, Pillar Two has received overall positive responses from the me-
dia and commentators. However, there have also been criticisms about the
specifics of the agreement. Common criticisms are that Pillar Two does not
251. Daniel Bunn, U.S. Cross-Border Tax Reform and the Cautionary Tale of GILTI,
T
AX FOUND. (Feb. 17, 2021), http://taxfoundation.org/gilti-us-cross-border-tax-reform/#Key.
252. Reuven S. Avi-Yonah & Nicola Sartori, Symposium on International Taxation and
Competitiveness: Introduction and Overview, 65 T
AX L. REV 313, 319 (2012); see also Big-
gest Companies in the World 2022,F
INANCECHARTS, http://www.financecharts.com/screener
/biggest (last visited Mar. 29, 2022) (indicating the top 10 companies are from the United
States).
253. I.R.C. § 11.
254. Sebastian Dueñas & Daniel Bunn, Tax Avoidance Rules Increase the Compliance
Burden in EU Member Countries,T
AX FOUND. (Mar. 28, 2019), http://taxfoundation.org/eu-
tax-avoidance-rules-increase-tax-compliance-burden (indicating that seventeen of twenty-
eight EU countries have exit taxes).
255. Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, For Haven’s Sake: Reflections on Inversion Transactions,
95 T
AX NOTES 1793 (June 17, 2002).
256.SeeDavid R. Tillinghast, A Matter of Definition: Foreign and Domestic Taxpayers,
2I
NTL TAX &BUS. L. 239, 252–53 (1984).
257. Christos Theophilou, Insight: Corporate Residence Post-BEPS and Global Mobili-
ty,B
LOOMBERG TAX (June 10, 2020, 3:00 AM), http://news.bloombergtax.com/daily-tax-
report-international/insight-corporate-residence-post-beps-and-global-mobility.
548 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
go far enough to ensure MNEs are taxed fairly, that various carve-outs and
exceptions make the agreement unbalanced, and that it is unclear what
would happen to Pillar Two in the implementation stage. This Subpart dis-
cusses these challenges and offers possible responses.
1. Priority to Residence-Based Taxation and
Developing Countries’ Concerns
It is true that Pillar Two is quite complex and possibly flawed since it
accords primacy to the country of residence by giving priority to IIR for res-
idence taxation over UTPR and STTR for source taxation. Thus, the source
country’s tax will only be applicable if the residence country chooses not to
tax.
The precedence of the IIR over the UTPR/STTR in Pillar Two has also
led to critiques of Pillar Two—namely that it is not reflective of the con-
cerns of developing countries that largely consist of source countries. For
example, the Tax Justice Network and Oxfam criticized the global mini-
mum tax for unfairly providing advantages to the world’s wealthier coun-
tries.
258
Specifically, they argue that the imposition of residence-based tax
on MNEs under the IIR will make it impossible for developing countries to
attract FDI by granting tax concessions, and that the UTPR and STTR are
meaningless if all the income of MNEs is already subject to the minimum
tax rate of fifteen percent under the IIR.
259
Despite lofty goals of ending tax
havens and tax competition, the critiques highlight sizeable incentives for
profit shifting that still remain due to exemptions and loopholes that the
global tax deal was supposed to curtail.
260
This critique is only partially valid, however. The first criticism about
the ability to attract FDI assumes that developing countries actually wish to
grant tax concessions to MNEs based on a cost/benefit analysis. This is not
true. Most empirical studies suggest that the main reason to allow tax con-
cessions, tax holidays, and tax competition is the threat of the MNEs going
elsewhere.
261
If that is the case, developing countries would benefit from the
IIR because it neutralizes the MNE’s ability to conduct such an auction by
subjecting it to the minimum tax wherever it goes.
It is true that if the UTPR/STTR for source taxation were given primacy
over the IIR for residence taxation then developing countries might gain
more revenue. However, it is not clear that in the absence of the IIR, devel-
258. Hamish Boland-Rudder & Spencer Woodman, 136 Countries Agree to Global Min-
imum Tax for Corporations in Historic’ OECD Deal,I
NTL CONSORTIUM INVESTIGATIVE
JOURNALISM (Oct. 8, 2021), http://www.icij.org/investigations/paradise-papers/136-countries-
agree-to-global-minimum-tax-for-corporations-in-historic-oecd-deal.
259.Id.
260.Id.
261. Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Bridging the North-South Divide: International Redistribu-
tion and Tax Competition, 26 M
ICH.J.INTL L. 371 (2004).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 549
oping countries would be able to impose taxes under the UTPR/STTR be-
cause, without the IIR for residence taxation, the MNE could threaten to go
elsewhere. In other words, the IIR neutralizes the behavioral incentives of
multinational taxpayers to engage in location shopping and the UTTR
/STTR neutralizes the incentive of source countries to engage in tax compe-
tition.
In addition, foreign tax credits will be available under the IIR just like
they are (with limitations) under GILTI. This means that, in practice, devel-
oping countries can impose source taxation on MNEs’ FDI, and those
MNEs will not suffer because these taxes will be credited against the resi-
dence taxation imposed by the IIR.
Finally, the substance carve-outs will enable developing countries to
engage in some level of tax competition for real investment. Large develop-
ing countries are also expected to gain significant additional revenue from
Pillar One. For all these reasons, we believe that the critique that Pillar Two
disadvantages developing countries is exaggerated.
262
Nonetheless, there might be an alternative to Pillar Two that imple-
ments the single tax principle more effectively with fewer concerns to de-
veloping countries. That is, Pillar Two may be tweaked in order to ensure
that countries can tax MNEs on both inbound and outbound investments.
This could be done by applying a substance-based test using a fractional ap-
portionment method in transfer pricing. This method would allocate MNEs’
profits that have not been effectively taxed amongst all countries in which a
MNE has a taxable presence. Once profits of MNEs are allocated among
relevant countries based on the substance-based test, each country would
impose taxes on such profits according to their own respective tax rates.
This alternative would not require the application of the complex IIR and
UTPR, and instead rely on fractional apportionment based on assets, per-
sonnel, and sales revenue (by locations of customers or users). While the
GloBE rules impose a top-up tax only in the country of residence,
263
this al-
ternative would allow all affected countries, either as residence or source, to
impose tax based on their respective shares of the undertaxed profits.
2. Various Carve-Outs
During the negotiation of Pillar Two in mid-2021, there were nine
countries that opposed it.
264
These countries included several in Europe,
262. For similar reasons, we respectfully oppose the argument that tax harmony and co-
operation envisioned in Pillar Two does not help developing countries. See Cui, supra note
31.
263.Statement, supra note 1, at 3–4.
264. Cliff Taylor & Ellen O’Riordan, Ireland One of 9 Countries to Hold Out on Signing
OECD Global Tax Deal,I
RISH TIMES (July 1, 2021, 5:08 PM), http://www.irishtimes.com
/business/economy/ireland-one-of-9-countries-to-hold-out-on-signing-oecd-global-tax-deal-
1.4609129; see also Jorge Liboreiro, Ireland, Hungary and Estonia Opt out of OECD
Tax Deal and Cast Shadow over EU’s Unified Position,E
URONEWS (Aug. 26, 2021),
550 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
namely Hungary, Ireland, and Estonia. Although they account for just four
percent of the EU’s economic output, they were in a position to deal a sig-
nificant blow to the prospects of the OECD’s tax plan.
265
Tax directives in
the EU require the unanimous consent of all twenty-seven member states,
effectively giving a single EU member veto power over the agreement.
266
Statements made by officials in each country emphasized that Ireland,
Hungary, and Estonia did not present a united front or adhere to a common
core principle.
267
Ireland supported Pillar One but demanded that the fifteen
percent global minimum tax rate be lower because its corporate tax rate is
12.5 percent.
268
Hungary had issues with the plan’s industry carve-outs.
269
Finally, Estonia simply wanted to preserve its unique tax system.
270
Eventually, the EU hold-out did not occur. One hundred and thirty-
seven countries, including Ireland, Hungary, and Estonia, agreed to the
global tax deal, including Pillar Two. However, the global tax deal now in-
cludes various carve-outs and reservations. For example, Ireland agreed to
http://www.euronews.com/2021/07/02/ireland-hungary-and-estonia-opt-out-of-oecd-tax-deal-
and-cast-shadow-over-eu-s-unified-pos (indicating the nine countries that did not sign on to
the OECD global deal are Ireland, Hungary, Estonia, Kenya, Nigeria, Peru, Sri Lanka, Barba-
dos, and Saint Vincent and the Grenadines).
265. Zoltan Simon & Peter Flanagan, European Trio Cast Dissatisfied Shadow over
Global Tax Accord,B
LOOMBERG (July 2, 2021), http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles
/2021-07-02/europe-s-new-awkward-squad-casts-shadow-over-global-tax-deal.
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2021-07-02/europe-s-new-awkward-
squad-casts-shadow-over-global-tax-deal
266. Christopher Condon, G-20 Finance Chiefs Back Tax Deal and Vow to Clear Hur-
dles,B
LOOMBERG (July 10, 2021), http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2021-07-10
/yellen-optimistic-congress-will-back-part-of-global-tax-deal. Cf. Faulhaber, supra note 23
(suggesting that even if one of the member states remains a hold-out, the EU can possibly still
implement the global minimum tax portion of the OECD plan through the issuance of a di-
rective. Whether the directive would survive a legal challenge is uncertain, but the fact that
the tax is a minimum tax makes winning the challenge more likely).
267. Stephanie Soong Johnston & Sarah Paez, Ireland, Estonia to Join OECD Global
Tax Reform Deal,T
AX NOTES (Oct. 11, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-international
/base-erosion-and-profit-shifting-beps/ireland-estonia-join-oecd-global-tax-reform-deal/2021
/10/11/7bbn3?highlight=opposition%20to%20OECD%20g.
268. Liz Alderman, Ireland’s Days as a Tax Haven May Be Ending, but Not Without a
Fight,N.Y.
T
IMES (July 12, 2021), http://www.nytimes.com/2021/07/08/business/ireland-
minimum-corporate-tax.html.
269. Elodie Lamer, Growing Unease in EU Over Global Tax Deal’s Next Steps,T
AX
NOTES (July 12, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-today-international/corporate-
taxation/growing-unease-eu-over-global-tax-deals-next-steps/2021/07/12
/76rz4?highlight=OECD.
270. Todd Buell, Estonian Official Airs Country’s Objections to Global Minimum Tax,
L
AW 360 (July 16, 2021), http://www.law360.com/tax-authority/international/articles/1403781
/estonian-official-airs-country-s-objections-to-global-minimum-tax. See also Kyle Pomerleau,
The Key Component of the Estonia’s Competitive Tax System,T
AX FOUND. (Oct. 6, 2015),
http://taxfoundation.org/key-component-estonia-s-competitive-tax-system (explaining that the
unique feature of Estonia’s corporate income tax system is a cash-flow tax, meaning corporate
income tax is only levied when business pay out to shareholders).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 551
end its 12.5 percent corporate tax rate and join the deal at the last minute,
“with assurances sought and received from the EU that it would not seek to
increase the tax rate further down the line.
271
Hungary obtained the ten-
year transition period, during which it may “offer a lower rate of tax for
tangible investments in its jurisdiction—such as automotive plants.”
272
Chi-
na also succeeded in having a clause inserted that would limit the effect of
the global minimum tax on companies who are starting to expand interna-
tionally—because of concerns that its growing domestic companies would
be clipped by the measures.
273
Commentators argue that these carve-outs and exemptions failed the
original ambition of the global tax deal. Instead of leveling the playing field,
the watered-down measures mean that only a “sliver of the profits” of
MNEs will become taxable, while incentives to shift profits remain siza-
ble.
274
Alex Coham, CEO of the Tax Justice Network, commented in a
statement that, “[i]t’s no wonder that Ireland and other havens have em-
braced the deal, especially after obtaining various concessions.
275
Civil so-
ciety organization, Oxfam, also criticized that the global deal panders to tax
havens and multinational corporations with exemptions and loopholes that
meant the new measures have “practically no teeth” and will offer no reve-
nue help to the world’s poorest countries.
276
We also disfavor these carve-outs. Some level of compromise is inevi-
table to achieve a global tax deal and bring almost 140 member states to the
negotiation table. However, the purpose of seeking a global deal for Pillar
Two is to accomplish tax harmony to end tax competition. These carve-outs
clearly violate the single tax principle by offering various methods for cer-
tain countries to continue tax competition, especially among source coun-
tries. What is worse, the carve-outs disturb tax harmony, weakening the ef-
fectiveness of Pillar Two measures among countries who are fully
committed to the single tax principle.
3. Logistical Puzzle
There is an additional concern about whether the global tax deal con-
sisting of Pillars One and Two could actually be implemented, especially in
271. Lisa O’Carroll, Ireland Ends 12.5% Tax Rate in OECD Global Pact, THE
GUARDIAN, (Oct. 7, 2021), http://www.theguardian.com/world/2021/oct/07/ireland-poised-to-
drop-125-tax-rate-in-oecd-global-pact.
272. Giles, et al., supra note 241.
273. Id.
274. Boland-Rudder & Woodman, supra note 258.
275. Alex Cobham, OECD Tax Deal Fails to Deliver, T
AX JUST. NETWORK (Oct. 8,
2021), http://taxjustice.net/press/oecd-tax-deal-fails-to-deliver.
276. Press Release, OXFAM Int’l, OECD Tax Deal is a Mockery of Fairness: Oxfam
(Oct. 8, 2021), http://www.oxfam.org/en/press-releases/oecd-tax-deal-mockery-fairness-oxfam.
552 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
the United States.
277
The goal is for countries to sign a multilateral conven-
tion during 2022 with an effective date of 2023, although most practitioners
view this timeline as highly unlikely. Political realities in the United States
illustrate the complexities of implementing the global tax agreement.
278
The
Biden Administration has a pretty thin majority in the Senate and in the
House of Representatives, so it is very doubtful that the G20/OECD interna-
tional tax plan will be passed by the U.S. Congress in a single bill, increas-
ing the difficulty of ratification in the U.S. Senate.
279
Considering that the
United States is important to have on board to ensure the effective imple-
mentation of both Pillars, the successful implementation of the global tax
deal is an open question.
Pillar One will alter U.S. treaties with other countries, and therefore will
need to be implemented through a multilateral treaty approved by two-thirds
of the U.S. Senate.
280
However, getting seventeen Republican senators to
support a treaty measure that many view as penalizing U.S. companies may
be a non-starter in the current economic and political climate.
281
The senior
Republicans on the tax-writing Senate Finance and House Ways and Means
committees already expressed opposition to Pillar One.
282
Furthermore, in a
joint statement, Senator Mike Crapo (R-Idaho) and Congressman Kevin
Brady (R-Texas) criticized the Biden Administration for pursuing the glob-
al tax deal agreement before Congress has acted on the administration’s
proposed changes to U.S. tax law, such as GILTI, calling into question how
quickly lawmakers may act on needed change.
283
They also mentioned in a
joint statement that “as other countries delay implementation and secure
side agreements and carve-outs to protect their own companies, U.S. busi-
nesses will be hit by tax increases ultimately borne by American workers,
277. Aime Williams, G7 Tax Deal Faces Opposition in US Congress, FIN. TIMES (June
9, 2021), http://www.ft.com/content/6c98b271-bd13-4517-81bb-6ef7f1798085.
278. James-Paul Galligan, Christine Green, Kevin Kelly & Kenneth Wear, OECD Tax
Deal: When Does it Become Law?, JDS
UPRA (Oct. 18, 2021), http://www.jdsupra.com
/legalnews/oecd-tax-deal-when-does-it-become-law-3448977.
279. Stephanie Soong Johnston, The End is Nigh: An Update on the OECD Tax Reform
Plan, F
ORBES (Oct. 19, 2021), http://www.forbes.com/sites/taxnotes/2021/10/19/the-end-is-
nigh-an-update-on-the-oecd-tax-reform-plan/?sh=353cdb891634.
280. Lilian Faulhaber, Will the OECD Plan Fix International Taxation?, L
AW360 (July
7, 2021), http://www.law360.com/articles/1400693.
281. Mindy Herzfeld, Pushing Pillar 1 Past Congress, T
AX NOTES (July 19, 2021),
http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-today-federal/fundamental-tax-system-structure/pushing-
pillar-1-past-congress/2021/07/19/76vyv?highlight=base%20erosion.
282. Lynch, supra note 247.
283. Letter from Senator Mike Crapo, Ranking Member, Comm. on Fin. & Congress-
man Kevin Brady, Ranking Member, Comm. on Ways and Means, to Senator Ron Wyden,
Chairman, Comm. on Fin. and Congressman Richard Neal, Chairman, Comm. on Ways and
Means (Sept. 2, 2021).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 553
savers and consumers.”
284
Hence, Senate approval of Pillar One in any form
will almost certainly require the inclusion of a ban on all current and future
DSTs, including the proposed EU digital levy.
285
Pillar Two, on the other hand, is generally compatible with existing tax
treaties and can likely be implemented with changes to domestic tax legisla-
tion.
286
Unlike Pillar One, Pillar Two can be implemented without any
changes in existing tax treaties as far as the IIR is concerned, as evidenced
by the United States unilaterally adopting GILTI.
287
UTPR and STTR may
require changes in tax treaties, but they are of secondary importance be-
cause they work conditionally. Since treaties are hard to change in the Unit-
ed States because of Senate ratification, this is an important advantage of
Pillar Two over Pillar One. We also anticipate that a lot of countries will be
implementing Pillar Two by domestic legislation, given the strong interest
in its development and the fact that it helps countries protect their tax base
by embodying a modern single tax principle.
Therefore, the Biden Administration may attempt to use the reconcilia-
tion process, only requiring a majority vote in the U.S. Senate, to push
through changes related to Pillar Two’s tax reform plan in the BBB Act and
negotiate with the Senate on Pillar One at a later time.
288
However, the $3.5 trillion USD BBB Act still faces obstacles in the
closely divided House and Senate. Some House Democrats have pushed
back against any increases to the GILTI tax.
289
Furthermore, the piecemeal
implementation of the global tax reform plan that will likely happen in the
United States will unfortunately create tension between the United States
and the EU when good faith and trust are required in order for the plan to be
fully implemented. Nonetheless, the logistical puzzle for implementing Pil-
lar Two in the United States is less significant compared to that for Pillar
One, which should go through treaty ratification process in the Senate.
284. Brady, Crapo: Biden Global Tax Deal Puts Politics Over Progress, Surrenders
Fate of U.S. Economy to Foreign Competitors,
U.S. SENATE COMM. ON FIN. (Oct. 8, 2021),
http://www.finance.senate.gov/ranking-members-news/brady-crapo-biden-global-tax-deal-
puts-politics-over-progress-surrenders-fate-of-us-economy-to-foreign-competitors.
285. Stephanie Soong Johnston, Crapo and Brady Urge Yellen to Push for Immediate
End to DSTs, T
AX NOTES (July 12, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-federal/digital-
economy/crapo-and-brady-urge-yellen-push-immediate-end-dsts/2021/07/12/76rtc?highlight=
OECD.
286. Faulhaber, supra note 23.
287. I.R.C. § 951A; see also Daniel Bunn, U.S. Cross-border Tax Reform and the Cau-
tionary Tale of GILTI, T
AX FOUND. (Feb. 17, 2021), http://taxfoundation.org/gilti-us-cross-
border-tax-reform (indicating that the U.S. adopted GILTI as an anti-base erosion rule).
288. Stephanie Soong Johnston, Reconciliation Bill May Have Global Minimum Tax
Provisions, T
AX NOTES (July 12, 2021), http://www.taxnotes.com/tax-notes-federal/politics-
taxation/reconciliation-bill-may-have-global-minimum-tax-provisions/2021/07/12/76rl1?highlight
=Pillar%201.
289. Alex Parker, How the Global Tax Agreement Could Backfire for Biden, L
AW360,
(Oct. 18, 2021), http://www.law360.com/tax-authority/articles/1431269/how-the-global-tax-
agreement-could-backfire-for-biden.
554 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
Hence, the United States’ enacting domestic legislation to implement
Pillar Two is the key to solving the logistical puzzle for the overall success
of the global tax reform plan as well as the modern single tax principle. To
make it possible, the two Pillars could be severed. The objective of both the
OECD and the United States seems to be to adopt both Pillars One and Two
as a package deal.
290
Both address the tax challenges in the digitalized
economy and combat the base erosion and profit shifting by MNEs. Howev-
er, Pillars One and Two are conceptually separate from each other—Pillar
One modernizes source-based taxation, whereas Pillar Two embodies the
single tax principle by reinforcing residence-based taxation. There is no log-
ical reason to treat the two Pillars as “linked by more than just politics,” as
the United States argues.
291
Furthermore, Pillar Two can be implemented by the G20 even if Pillar
One collapses because some countries refuse to abolish DSTs. In other
words, Pillar Two does not need universal implementation by all IF member
states because it is a measure that a country can implement to protect its
own tax base, irrespective of what other countries do. Hence, it is less criti-
cal, although not desirable, if a low-tax jurisdiction does not implement Pil-
lar Two, because the domestic legislation resulting from Pillar Two will al-
low the residence country to essentially tax back the income that has not
been taxed in the low-tax jurisdiction. Moreover, over ninety percent of
large MNEs are headquartered in the G20,
292
so only a relatively small
number of countries need to agree to implement an effective global mini-
mum tax. However, Pillar Two still requires international cooperation
among the G20 countries to adopt the harmonized domestic legislation that
is essential to stopping tax competition, base erosion, and profit shifting.
Thus, the United States should cooperate with the G20 countries to enact
Pillar Two even if Pillar One fails. Risking Pillar Two to salvage Pillar One
is unwise and regrettable because Pillar Two would be the first global tax
harmony in substantive tax law guided by the single tax principle.
CONCLUSION
In L’ancien Regime et la Revolution (1856), Alexis de Tocqueville ar-
gued that the roots of the radical changes imposed by the French Revolution
could be found in the Old Regime it sought to replace.
293
Similarly, the
roots of the new international tax regime as embodied in the Statement can
be traced to the benefits principle and the single tax principle, both of which
290. U.S. Dept of the Treasury, Presentation by the United States to the Steering Group
of the Inclusive Framework Meeting (2021), http://www.politico.com/f/?id=00000178-b389-
d098-a97a-f79960510001 (slide seven).
291.Id.
292. Saez & Zucman, supra note 67.
293. A
LEXIS DE TOCQUEVILLE,LANCIEN RÉGIME ET LA RÉVOLUTION [THE OLD
REGIME AND THE REVOLUTION] (7th ed. 1866).
2022] The Promise and Pitfalls of the Global Minimum Tax 555
stem from the origins of the international tax regime a century ago. The
benefits principle was the compromise between the claims of residence and
source jurisdictions reached by the four economists in 1923,
294
while the
single tax principle can be traced to Thomas Adams in 1918 and the League
of Nations experts in 1927.
295
However, unlike what happened in the French
Revolution, the Statement does not entirely replace the old international tax
regime. Instead, the Statement is an evolution from, or improvement of, the
benefits principle and the single tax principle.
Nevertheless, the new international tax regime envisaged in the two Pil-
lars in the Statement is also revolutionary. Pillar One (if implemented) will
partially remove the two main obstacles to taxing modern MNEs operating
in the digital economy, namely the physical presence requirement and the
arm’s-length standard. Pillar Two will fully implement the single tax princi-
ple on a global level for the first time through strengthening both source and
residence taxation with various secondary corrective measures. It will raise
significant revenue for the participating countries, stop tax competition, and
reduce base erosion and profit shifting. However, the proposed global min-
imum tax rate of fifteen percent would be lower than the average G20 cor-
porate tax rate, and substance carve-outs would maintain some double non-
taxation. Additionally, it may disproportionately harm developing countries
more than developed countries.
However, these flaws in Pillar Two could be eliminated based on the
outcome of current negotiations in the United States over reforming GILTI.
The U.S. GILTI rule, together with BEAT, has been grandfathered as ful-
filling the IIR and UTPR of Pillar Two. President Biden has proposed rais-
ing the GILTI rate to twenty-one percent and eliminating the participation
exemption. Also, the President has proposed replacing BEAT with Stopping
Harmful Inversions and Ending Low-Tax Developments (“SHIELD”),
which is designed explicitly to fit the UTPR of Pillar Two, because it im-
poses withholding tax on U.S. source income only if there is not adequate
taxation at the residence country.
296
Unfortunately, the BBB Act did not in-
corporate all of the President’s proposals. If, however, the United States
adopts these reforms, it is likely to generate a race to the top” as other
294.Seesupra text accompanying notes 62–64.
295.Seesupratext accompanying notes 73–74.
296. Stopping Harmful Inversions and Ending Low-Tax Developments (“SHIELD”)
would deny corporate deductions by reference to payments to foreign related persons that are
subject to a low effective tax rate, unless the income is subject to an acceptable minimum tax
regime. SHIELD is intended to more effectively target profit shifting to low-taxed jurisdic-
tions compared to BEAT, while simultaneously providing a strong incentive for other nations
to enact global minimum tax regimes. U.S.
D
EPT OF THE TREASURY,THE MADE IN
AMERICA TAX PLAN 11–12 (2021), http://home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/MadeInAmerica
TaxPlan_Report.pdf.
556 Michigan Journal of International Law [Vol. 43:3
countries follow suit, especially since SHIELD will put pressure on resi-
dence countries to adopt the IIR.
297
Overall, Pillar Two promises to finally break the back of tax competi-
tion by implementing the single tax principle harmoniously. Successful im-
plementation of Pillar Two should enable both developed and developing
countries to maintain free trade and globalization while also retaining and
strengthening the social safety net from the added revenues extracted from
the world’s largest corporations. We should all hope that in the face of the
pressures of de-globalization and rising nationalism, the new international
tax regime seeking tax harmony will survive and enable all countries to
overcome tax competition and maintain a robust social safety net for their
citizens.
297. A similar race to the top occurred when the United States adopted the CFC rules in
the 1960s, followed by over thirty other countries, including most of the G20. Reuven S. Avi-
Yonah, Constructive Unilateralism: U.S. Leadership and International Taxation, 42 I
NTL
TAX J. 17 (2016).